ELECTRICITY MARKETS AND THE SOCIAL PROJECT OF DECARBONIZATION

ELECTRICITY MARKETS AND THE SOCIAL PROJECT OF DECARBONIZATION

Decarbonization is the process of converting our economy from one that runs predominantly on energy derived from fossil fuels to one that runs almost exclusively on clean, carbon-free energy. If pursued on the scale that experts believe necessary to prevent dangerous climate change, the infrastructure changes required to decarbonize the United States will have significant social and cultural implications. States aggressively pursuing decarbonization have adopted policies reflecting their under-standing that decarbonization is a social project implicating numerous value choices. Various state decarbonization policies combine the aim of decarbonization with job promotion, economic development, income redistribution, urban revitalization, open-space preservation, and the continuation of traditional livelihoods.

These multifaceted state climate policies are multiplying in the Trump era, as federal alternatives recede. But variegated state policies present a challenge to the smooth functioning of U.S. electricity markets, which operate across states to supply least-cost power on a region-wide basis. To address this friction, regulators at the federal and state levels are considering a novel solution: Perhaps these markets should incorporate the aim of decarbonization rather than leaving this job for the states. There is a clear argument in favor of such reforms—they would allow states to accomplish decarbonization at lower cost while protecting electricity markets from distortionary state policies.

Nevertheless, this Article questions the widespread enthusiasm for using regional electricity markets, rather than states, as the primary drivers of decarbonization. Rather than accounting for the social and cultural values at stake in decarbonization, the process of integrating decarbonization into electricity markets prioritizes the aim of least-cost decarbonization above all else—thus rejecting states’ more capacious understandings of the goals of decarbonization. Moreover, regional electricity markets are quasi-private, complexly structured membership organizations, which operate under federal oversight and provide limited formal channels for state input. Consequently, if regional electricity markets become the primary locus of decarbonization policy, states will have given away a rich set of policy tools for publicly, creatively, and flexibly managing the trajectory of decarbonization. Understanding decarbonization as a social project thus provides new stakes in the otherwise technocratic debate over electricity markets and climate change, highlighting the importance of maintaining the public voice in critical decisions made around how to decarbonize.

INTRODUCTION

  1. THE CURRENT MESH AND CLASH OF REGIONAL ELECTRICITY MARKETS AND STATE CLIMATE POLICIES
    1. Electricity Markets
    2. State Climate Policies
    3. Tensions at the Intersection
  2. WHAT SHOULD WE ASK OF DECARBONIZATION? PREFERENCES BEYOND LEAST COST
    1. Two Visions of the Decarbonized Future
    2. State Policies as Reflections of the Social Project of Decarbonization
    3. Is It All Just Rent Seeking?
  3. ELECTRICITY-MARKET REDESIGN TO ACCOMPLISH THE PROJECT OF DECARBONIZATION
    1. Proposed Market Reforms to Achieve State Policies
    2. How a Stakeholder Proposal Becomes a Tariff Provision: The Intricacies of RTO Governance
    3. Resulting Challenges for RTO Control of Decarbonization
      1. A Loss of Public Procedure
      2. Homogenization and the Watering Down of Preferences
      3. The Risk of Aggrandizing Market Control
  4. IMPLICATIONS FOR CURRENT ELECTRICITY-LAW DEBATES
    1. Deciding Whether to Regionalize Through Electricity Markets
      1. Relative Priority of Least-Cost Solutions
      2. Evolving Legal Risk
      3. Regional Politics
    2. Thinking Outside the Market: State-Led Climate Policy Regionalization
    3. Designing Markets to Accommodate, Rather than Achieve, State Policies
    4. But What About the Laggards?

CONCLUSION

Introduction

One of the Trump Administration’s priorities during its first year has been the rollback of federal actions to address climate change. In addition to reconsidering several critical domestic regulations, 1 Exec. Order No. 13,783, 82 Fed. Reg. 16,093, 16,093–95 (Mar. 28, 2017) (revok­ing several of President Obama’s climate-related actions and ordering further review of various environmental regulations). President Trump announced on June 1, 2017, his intention to withdraw the United States from the Paris Accord 2             Statement by President Trump on the Paris Climate Accord, White House (June 1, 2017), http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/2017/06/01/statement-president-trump-paris-climate-accord [http://perma.cc/RPC7-ZD8J]. —the landmark international agreement on climate change signed by 195 parties. 3 Paris Agreement—Status of Ratification, United Nations Climate Change, http://unfccc.int/paris_agreement/items/9444.php [http://perma.cc/49U8-5QUL] (last visited Jan. 18, 2018) (showing signing and ratification status). Shortly after this announcement, U.S. states struck back in an aggressive demonstration of their resurgent place in cli­mate policy. In a letter titled “We Are Still In,” several states declared that “[i]n the absence of leadership from Washington,” they would “work[] together to take forceful action and to ensure that the U.S. remains a global leader in reducing emissions.” 4 “We Are Still In” Declaration, We Are Still In, http://www.wearestillin.com/we-are-still-declaration [http://perma.cc/SRL6-QR9U] (last visited Jan. 18, 2018). States are joined in the letter by tribes, cities, colleges, universities, businesses, and investors. Id. Nine states have signed as of January 2018. See id. States are backing up this promise with escalating state laws aimed at “decarbonization”—that is, the process of ending reliance on energy sources that emit carbon pollution. 5 See infra section I.B.

Leading states have passed legislation to reduce carbon emissions in their jurisdictions 80% by 2050, with a focus on reducing carbon pollu­tion from electricity. 6 For a catalog of states embracing this goal, see infra note 72 and accompanying text. Decarbonizing electricity is critical because experts predict that global greenhouse gas emissions must approach zero in the coming decades, even though electricity con­sumption is expected to double as transportation electrifies. See 2 James H. Williams et al., Energy & Envtl. Econ., Inc. & Deep Decarbonization Pathways Project, Policy Implications of Deep Decarbonization in the United States 4 (2015) [hereinafter Williams et al., Deep Decarbonization Policy], http://deepdecarbonization.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/11/
US_Deep_Decarbonization_Policy_Report.pdf
[http://perma.cc/T9FD-TD2C] (“Limiting warming to 2°C or less, an objective agreed upon by the international community, will require that global net [greenhouse gas] emis­sions approach zero by the second half of the 21st century.”); see also William Boyd & Ann E. Carlson, Accidents of Federalism: Ratemaking and Policy Innovation in Public Utility Law, 63 UCLA L. Rev. 810, 812 (2016) (“[D]ecarbonizing the electric power sector is far and away the most important component of any effort to meet ambitious U.S. [green­house gas] reduction targets by 2050 and beyond.”).
These are ambitious goals, likely to require the replacement of significant infrastructure at substantial expense. 7 See Emily Hammond & Jim Rossi, Stranded Costs and Grid Decarbonization, 82 Brook. L. Rev. 645, 663–64 (2017) (noting that decarbonization “stands to be one of the most significant economic transformations the economy has experienced in the last cen­tury”); see also infra note 281. And yet, in setting policies to achieve these goals, no state has adopted a purely market-based system that aims to reduce emissions at the lowest cost above all other goals. 8 See, e.g., Jim Rossi, Carbon Taxation by Regulation, 102 Minn. L. Rev. 277, 298–99 (2017) [hereinafter Ross, Carbon Taxation] (noting that various approaches to inter­nal subsidies “fall considerably short of the efficiency and social-welfare benefits that a carbon tax could provide”). Instead, states have crafted schemes that help them manage the contours, aims, and consequences of decarbonization. These state policies include requirements that utilities buy certain amounts and types of renewable energy, incentives for communities to build their own solar farms, payments to aging (and appealingly carbon-free) nuclear power plants to keep them from retiring, and complete redesign of state electricity law. 9 See infra section I.B. These various policies combine decarbo­nization with aims ranging from job creation and economic development to income redis­tribution, urban revitalization, open-space preservation, and the continu­ation of traditional livelihoods. 10 See infra sections I.B, II.B.

There is, however, a potential downside to this rich set of state climate policies. As state ambitions ramp up, complications with this state-by-state approach to decarbonizing electricity become more apparent. States share jurisdiction over electricity with the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC). 11 See 16 U.S.C. § 824(b) (2012) (providing federal jurisdiction over “the transmis­sion of electric energy in interstate commerce and to the sale of electric energy at whole­sale in interstate commerce,” but otherwise reserving authority for states). For more detail, see infra Part I. In most of the country, states have ceded partial control over electricity supply to regional electricity-market operators, which are “hybrid” quasi-private, quasi-governmental entities, comprised of industry members functioning under FERC oversight. 12 See Hari M. Osofsky & Hannah J. Wiseman, Hybrid Energy Governance, 2014 U. Ill. L. Rev. 1, 6 (describing how “the tripartite energy system [of physical, regulatory, and market components] involve[s] numerous public and private stakeholders at multiple levels of government”). Electricity-market structures are discussed in sections I.A and III.B. These electri­city markets are designed to select least-cost sources of electricity; they do not “price in” carbon or otherwise favor carbon-free generation sources. 13 See infra note 55 and accompanying text (noting that electricity markets are designed for least-cost electricity and are therefore limited in accommodating other goals); see also infra text accompanying note 237 (describing the aims of a carbon-pricing scheme). Consequently, many allege that state incentives and payment schemes targeted at particular low-carbon technologies inter­fere with the smooth functioning of these regional markets. 14 See infra section I.C.

Now, faced with a growing number of divergent state policies, several regional market operators have accepted that electricity markets may need to play a more active role in decarbonization. 15 See infra sections I.C, III.A; see also William Boyd, Public Utility and the Low-Carbon Future, 61 UCLA L. Rev. 1614, 1686–87 (2014) (“From a climate change perspec­tive . . . the looming question is whether electricity markets can deliver significant carbon reductions over the next several decades.”). One key question under discussion is whether it is time to redesign electricity markets to achieve states’ decarbonization goals. 16 Many people in this conversation distinguish between two ways that markets could be redesigned to support state climate policies. Markets could either be tweaked to accommodate state policies without attempting to supplant them, or markets could be used to achieve state climate goals. See Cheryl A. LaFleur, Comm’r, FERC, Remarks at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO New England Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc., and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 229–30 (May 1, 2017) [hereinafter LaFleur, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170530122035-Transcript,%20May%201,%202017.pdf [http://perma.cc/QNK2-7SZZ] (distinguishing between “achieve”-style solutions, in which markets are redesigned to accomplish state policy goals, and “accommodate”-style solutions, in which markets are adjusted to function around state policy goals); Memorandum from New England States Comm. on Elec. to New England Power Pool 1–2 (Apr. 7, 2017) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (discussing NESCOE’s feedback on the “long-term ‘achieve’-style proposals,” as well as NESCOE’s plan to assess a “short-term, ‘accommodate’-style proposal”). This Article focuses on the “achieve” category of solutions, although it briefly touches upon the poten­tial to accommodate state policies. See infra Part IV. Such proposals gained momen­tum in May 2017 when FERC convened a conference to consider their feasibility and desirability. 17 See FERC Calendar of Events, FERC, http://www.ferc.gov/EventCalendar/
Event
Details.aspx?ID=8663&CalType=%20&CalendarID=116&Date=&View=Listview [http://
perma.cc/G7B4-JUEN] (last visited Jan. 18, 2018).
In her opening remarks, then-acting FERC Chair Cheryl LaFleur identified these potential reforms as “the most critical issue [the agency was] confronting.” 18 LaFleur, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 16, at 9. Since that time, debates have intensified regard­ing how much of a challenge renewable energy pre­sents to electricity markets and how best to manage the shifting composi­tion of electricity-market resources. 19 Most notably—and to the consternation of many—the Department of Energy recently requested that FERC consider providing subsidies to “fuel-secure” nuclear and coal plants as a way to respond to changes in market dynamics that have ren­dered these resources less competitive than natural gas and renewable energy in many parts of the country. See Grid Resiliency Pricing Rule, 82 Fed. Reg. 46,940, 46,945 (Oct. 10, 2017) (to be codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35). For those expressing consternation, see, e.g., Sonal Patel, What States Told FERC About the DOE’s Grid Resiliency Rule, PowerMag (Oct. 25, 2017), http://www.powermag.com/what-states-told-ferc-about-the-does-grid-resiliency-rule-infographic [http://perma.cc/93ZV-2V5F] (mapping state responses to the DOE’s pro­posal and showing many states in key RTO regions to be “strongly opposed”); Jeff St. John, DOE’s Coal, Nuclear Cost Recovery Plan Receives Onslaught of Opposition, Greentech Media (Oct. 24, 2017), http://www.greentechmedia.com/articles/read/doe-coal-nuclear-cost-recovery-opposition-perry#gs.6b25rRU [http://perma.cc/MW92-GAHA] (“The pro­posal has drawn a backlash from major sectors of the energy industry, and the critique of two of three seated FERC commissioners at present, based on the potentially dire impacts it could have on the country’s relatively well-run and low-cost electricity markets.”). Section IV.C discusses the DOE Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NOPR) in more detail. For FERC’s response, see infra notes 332–334.

There is obvious appeal to using electricity markets to achieve state climate change goals. Integrating these goals into markets could lower the cost of decarbonizing energy, while eliminating the risk that accret­ing state policies might distort the functioning of electricity markets. For this reason, many stakeholders that often find themselves on opposite sides of energy policy debates have expressed support for integrating state climate policies into regional electricity markets. 20 Of note, several environmental not-for-profits find themselves aligned with fossil fuel generators on this topic. See infra Part III; see also Gavin Bade, The Carbon Consensus: Generators, Analysts Back CO2 Price at FERC Technical Conference, Util. Dive (May 3, 2017), http://www.utilitydive.com/news/the-carbon-consensus-generators-analysts-
back-co2-price-at-ferc-technical/441862/
[http://perma.cc/4F9N-UWNS] (“[O]ne note­worthy area of consensus emerged from nearly every corner of the diverse stakeholder group—the need to price carbon in wholesale power markets.”).
It can thus feel almost reflexively reactionary for anyone who supports rapid decarboni­zation to resist such efforts.

Nevertheless, this Article argues that states should exercise caution in ceding control over decarbonization too quickly or thoroughly to regional electricity markets. This argument is grounded in comparative institu­tional competencies 21 See Neil K. Komesar, Imperfect Alternatives: Choosing Institutions in Law, Economics, and Public Policy 4–6 (1994) (arguing that “deciding who decides” is a critical part of legal analysis and calling for greater attention to comparative institutional analysis). and the importance of preserving state cen­trality in decisionmaking over decarbonization. 22 “State” in this context refers to government. This Article does not intend to make a federalism argument, but rather proceeds on the assumption that states will be the level of government that primarily addresses decarbonization for the next several years. See Rossi, Carbon Taxation, supra note 8, at 278 (describing federal carbon tax legislation as “infeasible and . . . stalled, at least for the foreseeable future”); see also infra section IV.D. In short, states do a dis­service to current and future residents if they cede the shape of decarbonization policy to market insiders and experts rather than subject these policy decisions to wider democratic inquiry, debate, and decisionmaking.

Although conversations about electricity markets and decarboniza­tion can quickly alienate all but the most technocratic insiders, decarbon­ization is far more than a technical project. Decarbonization policies will determine how our society extracts, owns, sites, manages, moves, consumes, and conserves electricity in the future. Given electric­ity’s centrality to modern life, such policies have the potential to radically alter political and economic power, as well as to shape the future of American land­scapes, communities, and daily living arrangements. 23 See infra section II.A. Decarbonization is thus a profoundly social project. 24 This point is well made outside the legal literature, see infra note 147, but its implications for climate law and policy are surprisingly undertheorized. In a forthcoming article, Professor Alice Kaswan explores how decarbonization’s society-wide impacts might inform our understanding of the drawbacks of market-based mechanisms more generally, but she does not address the proposal to use regional electricity markets in particular. See Alice Kaswan, Energy, Governance, and Market Mechanisms, 72 Miami L. Rev. (forthcoming 2018) (manuscript at 1–11) (on file with the Columbia Law Review).

In crafting multifaceted, nuanced decarbonization policies, states are demonstrating their understanding of this fact. State climate policies reflect state preferences about how they decarbonize, instead of just whether they decarbonize. These diverse public preferences would be lost in the integration of state policy aims into regional electricity markets. This Article identifies three particular risks electricity markets present in this regard. The first is the loss of transparent, government-driven deci­sionmaking on the trajectory of decarbonization. Electricity markets are governed through quasi-private, immensely technocratic, and largely opaque processes 25 See infra section III.A. —hardly the space in which we should center debates over the shape of decarbonization. The second risk is one of homogeni­zation to the lowest common denominator. Electricity-market design lim­its the tools with which states can respond to decarbonization, requiring states to homogenize their preferences. In practice, such homogeniza­tion is likely to water down more ambitious state policies to achieve the near-consensus buy-in of states and stakeholders required in regional electricity-market governance.

The final risk to electricity-market integration of state climate poli­cies stems from the Supreme Court’s 2016 decision in Hughes v. Talen Energy Marketing, LLC. 26 136 S. Ct. 1288 (2016). There, the Supreme Court placed limits on states’ abilities to adopt policies that regulate electricity in ways too closely linked to federally overseen markets. 27 Id. at 1299. Although Hughes left open significant questions regarding how much overlap there can be between regional-market functions and state policy aims, it creates legal risk around any state decision to cede decarbonization goals to the markets. 28 See infra section III.B. Once a state gives control over a particular function—like decarboniza­tion—to its regional market, it may diminish the set of tools that it can use at the state level to accomplish the same policy aim.

Articulating these reasons for caution does not mean that states should resist all efforts to integrate decarbonization aims into regional electricity markets. Instead, these risks point to a series of conclusions about when market integration of state climate policies is advisable and how it might best proceed. First, states might prefer using regional elec­tricity markets as a climate tool when their objective is the cheapest decar­bonization possible, without regard for what resources the market selects or where these resources are located. In contrast, if a state has resource preferences, distributional goals, or other objectives related to how decar­bonization proceeds, markets will prove inapt tools. For these states, market integration may prove advisable only if the particular mar­ket reform selected allows states leeway to adjust their preferences and factor them into the market design. 29 Part IV explains how certain market reforms might allow for this more easily than others.

Second, the regional politics of decarbonization should inform state decisions. U.S. states diverge considerably in the ambition of their climate policies, from states pledging to go “100% renewable” to states focused on perpetuating U.S. coal consumption. 30 For a catalog of some of the most ambitious state renewable energy targets, see generally infra notes 87–88. For state support of coal, see generally Kathiann M. Kowalski, As Ohio Legislature Regroups, Power Plant Subsidy Debate to Continue, Midwest Energy News (Aug. 16, 2017), http://midwestenergynews.com/2017/08/16/as-ohio-legislature-regroups-power-plant-subsidy-debate-continues/ [http://perma.cc/88NJ-RATC] (detailing legislative efforts in Ohio to provide subsidies to “1950s-era coal plants” and nuclear generation). As this Article explains, the struc­ture of U.S. electricity law leaves regional market enti­ties without the authority to mandate that recalcitrant states adopt more aggressive cli­mate policies. 31 See infra section IV.C. Nevertheless, perhaps there is still some bargaining power inherent in the regional market construct, such that states aggressive on climate change might use market solutions to coax along less willing regional neighbors. The greater the likelihood of such persuasion suc­ceeding, the more appealing a market-based solution should be. 32 See infra section IV.A.

Finally, the appeal of integrating state policies into regional markets might shift over time as courts flesh out the boundaries of the Hughes deci­sion and related cases. 33 See infra section III.C. Because of these variables at play, the ques­tion of how to manage the intersection of state policies and regional electricity markets is likely to be a dynamic and region-specific one. Nevertheless, there is value in understanding at the outset of these conversations the risks that the marketization of state climate policies presents to the multi­faceted project of decarbonization. Only states ready to relinquish control over their decarbonization trajectory in exchange for cost effectiveness should embrace market integration proposals as they stand now.

Most scholarly analysis of these proposed electricity-market reforms has focused on the jurisdictional questions they present. Regional elec­tricity-market operators are constrained by the Federal Power Act’s man­date that federally overseen markets ensure “just and reasonable” rates. 34 See 16 U.S.C. § 824d (2012). Whether integrating decarbonization goals falls within this mandate is a thorny legal question, and many prominent energy law scholars are puz­zling through this jurisdictional morass. 35 See 2 Steven Weissman & Romany Webb, Berkeley Ctr. for Law, Energy & the Env’t, Addressing Climate Change Without Legislation: FERC § 3.1 (2014), http://
www.law.berkeley.edu/files/CLEE/FERC_Report_FINAL.pdf [http://perma.cc/5XE7-R4Q7] (“In addition to considering . . . supplier and customer interests, FERC’s rate­making must also protect the general public interest.”); Christopher J. Bateman & James T. B. Tripp, Toward Greener FERC Regulation of the Power Industry, 38 Harv. Envtl. L. Rev. 275, 278 (2014) (arguing that the Federal Power Act (FPA) authorizes FERC to consider the environmental effects of power generation in setting just and reasonable rates); Joel Eisen, FERC’s Expansive Authority to Transform the Electric Grid, 49 U.C. Davis L. Rev. 1783, 1788 (2016) (arguing that “the FPA’s terms are not frozen in amber, as the statute has adapted to changing market realities” and that, in FERC v. Electric Power Supply Ass’n (FERC v. EPSA), 136 S. Ct. 760 (2016), “the Court has properly confirmed that the FPA has flexibility to address modern developments in the electric grid”); Ari Peskoe, Easing Jurisdictional Tensions by Integrating Public Policy in Wholesale Electricity Markets, 38 Energy L.J. 1, 1 (2017) (exploring “FERC’s authority under the [FPA] to approve a wholesale market tariff that facilitates market participants’ achievement of their legal obligations under renewable energy and CO2 policies”); Rossi, Carbon Taxation, supra note 8, at 330 (arguing that “FERC has the authority to adopt grid-system-reliability adders reflecting the carbon attributes of different energy resources”); see also Kate Konschnik & Ari Peskoe, Harvard Envtl. Law Program Policy Initiative, Minimizing Constitutional Risk: Crafting State Energy Policies that Can Withstand Constitutional Scrutiny 11–15 (2014), http://statepowerproject.files.wordpress.com/2014/11/minimizing-constitutional-risk2.pdf [http://perma.cc/JS8G-SPGZ] (noting that “[s]tate regulation of wholesale rates is . . . generally field preempted” and highlighting three policies that may constitute impermissible ratemaking—mandating feed-in tariffs, guaranteeing generator revenue in regions with federally regulated auction markets, and pricing renewable energy credits); Matthew R. Christiansen, FERC v. EPSA: Functionalism and the Electricity Industry of the Future, 68 Stan. L. Rev. Online 100, 101–02 (2016), http://www.stanfordlawreview.org/
online/ferc-v-epsa/ [http://perma.cc/4LQ8-KSVJ] (describing the Supreme Court’s analysis in FERC v. EPSA as “eschewing some of the rhetoric regarding ‘bright line’ [jurisdictional] rules on which the Court had relied in previous FPA cases in favor of a more flexible approach that applied the FPA’s basic prem­ise to the changing industry”); Joel B. Eisen, Dual Electricity Federalism Is Dead, but How Dead, and What Replaces It?, 8 Geo. Wash. J. Energy & Envtl. L. 3, 6 (2017) [hereinafter Eisen, Dual Electricity] (arguing that Hughes v. Talen Energy Marketing, LLC, 136 S. Ct. 1288 (2016), “raises more questions than it answers about which state initiatives are permissible”); Emily Hammond, Hughes v. Talen Energy Marketing, LLC: Energy Law’s Jurisdictional Boundaries—Take Three, Geo. Wash. L. Rev. Docket (2016), http://www.gwlr.org/hughes-v-talen-energy-marketing-llc-energy-laws-jurisdictional-boundaries-take-three [http://perma.cc/4WEF-ABWE] (“Hughes doesn’t really tell us which state initiatives will survive future Supremacy Clause challenges and which will fail.”); Hannah J. Wiseman, Disaggregating Preemption in Energy Law, 40 Harv. Envtl. L. Rev. 293, 294 (2016) (noting that the question of which level of government should regu­late an activity is “contentious” and suggesting a preemption framework for energy law).

Less explored, however, is the question of whether states should want regional markets to perform this service, legality aside. Often, energy law scholars approach such questions over state versus regional market con­trol through the lens of federalism—asking whether FERC or the states are better positioned to take the lead. 36 See, e.g., Boyd & Carlson, supra note 6, at 812–20; Felix Mormann, Clean Energy Federalism, 67 Fla. L. Rev. 1621, 1625–30 (2015); Jim Rossi, The Brave New Path of Energy Federalism, 95 Tex. L. Rev. 399, 403 (2016) [hereinafter Rossi, Brave New Path]. This Article frames these debates differently, highlighting the ways in which they implicate long-standing institutional design choices between complex, heavily managed market constructs and more direct regulatory control by states. 37 Professor William Boyd began an evocative exploration of these themes in Public Utility and the Low-Carbon Future, in which he argues that electricity markets are part of “a broader understanding of public utility” and should be harnessed to normative ends. Boyd, supra note 15, at 1673. Boyd’s analysis frames but does not answer the question tack­led here—how, within this normative project, states should weigh the relative merits of using markets or regulation to accomplish their decarbonizing aims. Professor Jim Rossi has similarly reframed the conversation by identifying ways in which state decarbonization policies resemble “carbon taxation by regulation.” See Rossi, Carbon Taxation, supra note 8, at 279–80. Rossi’s focus, however, is on how these regulatory instruments can be made to resemble market mechanisms—a line of inquiry that deviates substantially from my own. See id.; see also infra note 170. Professor David B. Spence also has insightful broader work on these themes. See generally David B. Spence, Naïve Energy Markets, 92 Notre Dame L. Rev. 973 (2017) [hereinafter, Spence, Naïve Energy Markets] (explaining how “energy markets can never resemble the idealized markets of economic theory that have become so popular in conservative policy discourse”). Framing the issue in this way lends relevance to a separate genre of scholarship, focused on questions of how markets, public policy, and values inter­sect. 38 See infra Part II. See generally Frank Ackerman & Lisa Heinzerling, Priceless: On Knowing the Price of Everything and the Value of Nothing (2005) (criticizing the assign­ment of monetary values to public health and environmental resources); Douglas A. Kysar, Regulating from Nowhere: Environmental Law and the Search for Objectivity (2010) (arguing against a utilitarian, welfare-maximization approach to environmental policy in favor of an approach that is more morally accountable); Mark Sagoff, The Economy of the Earth: Philosophy, Law, and the Environment (2d ed. 2008) (describing two conceptions of the environment—as intrinsically sacrosanct and as a source of economic value—and arguing that society must balance the two conceptions); Michael J. Sandel, What Money Can’t Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets (2012) (challenging the predominance of markets and market-oriented thinking in the modern era); Boyd, supra note 15 (arguing that a narrow conception of “public utility” has distorted understandings of the role of markets and discussing its relationship to decarbonization). Drawing from this literature, the Article illuminates the ways in which decarbonization is a normative societal project—one with con­tested visions and outcomes. Decarbonization might radically redistribute wealth and power in U.S. society, or it might largely maintain the status quo while shifting only behind-the-scenes fuel choices. 39 See infra section II.A. State policies reflect and embody this contest while regional markets present a homog­enizing and privatizing force that narrows the room in which to debate the many shapes a decarbonized society might take.

This Article proceeds in four parts. Part I gives an overview of regional electricity markets, state climate change policies, and their inter­sections. Part II explores the nature of the project of decarbonization, illus­trating how state climate policies embody diverse preferences and values that reflect an understanding of the significant choices at hand. Part III shows how electricity-market redesign might eliminate these democrat­ically determined value choices embedded in state climate poli­cies, laying out the challenges that result from using the peculiar governance structures of electricity markets to carry out decarbonization. Part IV presents lessons derived from this analysis for when states might pre­fer or resist market integration of their decarbonization goals.

I. The Current Mesh and Clash of Regional Electricity Markets and State Climate Policies

To understand the debates about decarbonization roiling electricity regulation, one has to begin with a foundation in the structure of elec­tricity policy and electricity markets. This Part provides an overview of regional electricity markets, state climate policies, and their potentially troubling intersections.

A. Electricity Markets

Electricity governance in the United States is a patchwork affair, tak­ing on various forms across states and regions that defy quick summa­tion. 40 Cf. Paul L. Joskow, Markets for Power in the United States: An Interim Assessment, 27 Energy J. 1, 4 (2006) (describing U.S. restructuring as occurring without “a clear coherent blueprint,” unlike in other countries). This patchwork quality stems from the Federal Power Act of 1935, which divides jurisdiction over electricity in the United States. The fed­eral government—acting via FERC—has jurisdiction over “the sale of [electric] energy at wholesale,” which comprises sales from electricity generators to the utilities that own the transmission and distribution grid that carries that electricity to end-use consumers. 41 16 U.S.C. § 824(a), (b)(1) (2012). States retain control over “retail sales” of electricity—sales that these utilities make to consumers. 42 Id. § 824(b)(1).

From 1935 until the 1990s, FERC had a fairly straightforward role in electricity regulation. Most utilities owned their own generation resources that they used to supply their retail customers, such that there were rela­tively few “wholesale transactions” of electricity to regulate. 43 Paul L. Joskow, Regulatory Failure, Regulatory Reform, and Structural Change in the Electrical Power Industry, 1989 Brookings Papers on Econ. Activity: Microeconomics 125, 134; see also Boyd & Carlson, supra note 6, at 824; David B. Spence, Can Law Manage Competitive Energy Markets?, 93 Cornell L. Rev. 765, 769–70 (2008) [hereinafter Spence, Can Law Manage?]. In cases in which one utility sold wholesale power to another, FERC fulfilled its duty to ensure “just and reasonable” rates 44 See 16 U.S.C. § 824a-3(b)(1). by requiring utilities to prefile the rates they intended to charge for FERC-jurisdictional sales. 45 See id. § 824d(c) (requiring such filings); W. Deptford Energy v. FERC, 766 F.3d 10, 12 (D.C. Cir. 2014) (“The Federal Power Act requires regulated utilities to file with the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, as a matter of open and accessible public record, any rates and charges they intend to impose for sales of electrical energy that are subject to the Commission’s jurisdiction.” (citing 16 U.S.C. § 824d(c))). At the same time, states had their own public utility commissions (PUCs) to regulate the rates that utilities could charge end-use customers. 46 See Boyd & Carlson, supra note 6, at 822–23. Thus, there was relatively little difference in the character of regulation at the state and federal levels—in either case, commissions oversaw regu­lated monopoly entities.

In the 1990s, Congress and FERC—following on the heels of deregu­lation in other major sectors, including airlines, trucking, communica­tions, and railroads—took significant steps to promote market constructs within federal electricity regulation. 47 See Energy Policy Act of 1992, Pub. L. No. 102-486, §§ 721–722, 106 Stat. 2776 (1992) (codified at 16 U.S.C. § 824j–k); Joskow, supra note 40, at 4–5 (describing FERC’s “initiatives to support the creation of competitive wholesale markets”); see also Joseph D. Kearney & Thomas W. Merrill, The Great Transformation of Regulated Industries Law, 98 Colum. L. Rev. 1323, 1323 (1998) (explaining how FERC issued orders “designed to increase the access of local distribution companies to lower-cost gas and to stimulate com­petition”); Joseph T. Kelliher & Maria Farinella, The Changing Landscape of Federal Energy Law, 61 Admin. L. Rev. 611, 613 (2009) (“[The] Federal Power Act and the Natural Gas Act have changed from a regulatory scheme that controlled market power exercise by utilities, pipelines, and producers through classic rate regulation to a regula­tory regime that controls the exercise of market power through reliance on a mixture of competition and regulation.”); Spence, Can Law Manage?, supra note 43, at 765 (“Over the last three decades, the world’s industrialized democracies have introduced competi­tion into previously noncompetitive, regulated markets.”). The first move in this direction was a requirement that utilities allow other utilities to utilize their transmis­sion lines at nondiscriminatory rates. 48 See Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-Discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities, 61 Fed. Reg. 21,540, 21,603 (Apr. 24, 1996) (codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35) (“[I]f a transmission provider offers a rate discount to its affiliate, or if the transmission provider attributes a discounted rate to its own trans­actions, the same discounted rate must also be offered at the same time to non-affiliates on the same transmission path and on all unconstrained transmission paths.”); Open Access Same-Time Information System (Formerly Real-Time Information Networks) and Standards of Conduct, 61 Fed. Reg. 21,737, 21,740 (Apr. 24, 1996) (codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 37) (“This final rule . . . will ensure that transmission customers have access to transmission information enabling them to obtain open access transmission service on a non-discriminatory basis.”). Around the same time, many states required their utilities to sell off generation assets so that the same company would no longer comprise both the supply and demand side of electricity transactions. 49 See Joskow, supra note 40, at 7 (noting that FERC “could not and did not” order utilities to do this, but state initiatives and market opportunities “led to a considerable amount of restructuring of the ownership of existing generating plants”); see also Robert J. Michaels, The Governance of Transmission Operators, 20 Energy L.J. 233, 236 (1999) (describing the regulatory actions taken by FERC in the late 1990s). With these two changes in place, the stage was set for the birth of electricity markets—exchanges in which generators could bid in offers to sell electricity and utilities could seek out the low­est-priced sources of electricity to supply their customers.

In 1999, FERC issued Order 2000, which encouraged—but did not require—states and utilities to form regional electricity-management organizations, called either “Regional Transmission Organizations” (RTOs) or “Independent System Operators” (ISOs). 50 There is no functional difference between RTOs and ISOs for the purposes of this Article, and this Article refers to all such entities as RTOs hereinafter. See Regional Transmission Organizations, 65 Fed. Reg. 810, 811 (Dec. 20, 1999) (codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35) (“Industry participants . . . retain flexibility in structuring RTOs that satisfy the minimum characteristics and functions. . . . The characteristics and functions could be satisfied by different organizational forms, such as ISOs . . . .”); see also Seth Blumsack, Measuring the Benefits and Costs of Regional Electric Grid Integration, 28 Energy L.J. 147, 147 n.1 (2007) (“There are some differences between ISOs and RTOs in their govern­ance structure and congestion management protocols. Operationally, ISOs and RTOs look very similar.”). These entities would be “independent grid management organizations” in charge of managing the transmission grid and running electricity markets to pro­cure and dis­patch least-cost electricity across the region. 51 See Regional Transmission Organizations, 65 Fed. Reg. at 813–15; see also Michael H. Dworkin & Rachel Aslin Goldwasser, Ensuring Consideration of the Public Interest in the Governance and Accountability of Regional Transmission Organizations, 28 Energy L.J. 543, 553 (2007) (listing RTOs’ multiple functions).

Some states and their utilities opted in; others declined—hence the patchwork nature of the present system. Today, seven RTOs serve around two-thirds of the U.S. population. 52 Susan F. Tierney, Senior Advisor, Analysis Grp., Remarks at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc., and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at n.1 (Apr. 26, 2017) [hereinafter Tierney, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/
CalendarFiles/20170426151811-Tierney,%20Analysis%20Group.pdf
[http://perma.cc/ 32J3-VVS7] (“The current U.S. population is 325 million. According to the ISO/RTO Council, the seven U.S. regional transmission organizations (RTO) and independent system operators (ISOs) provide service in regions where 218 million people live . . . .” (citation omitted)).
These RTOs range in size from single-state (for example, those that serve New York or California) to fifteen-state (for example, MISO, the RTO serving the upper Midwest). 53 About MISO, MISO, http://www.misoenergy.org/AboutUs/Pages/AboutUs.aspx [http://perma.cc/FKZ4-SKX8] (last visited Jan. 18, 2018); ISO/RTO Council, NYISO, http://www.nyiso.com/public/markets_operations/services/planning/iso_rto/index.jsp [http://perma.cc/9Q9E-44Y5] (last visited Apr. 14, 2018) (mapping New York and California ISOs). FERC oversees all of these regional entities except for that of Texas, whose RTO has no interstate transmission connections to bring it within federal jurisdiction. 54 Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT), FERC, http://www.ferc.gov/
industries/electric/indus-act/rto/ercot.asp
[http://perma.cc/PQ4X-DFPW] (last updated Nov. 17, 2015).
As a general matter, states outside of these regions continue to exercise sub­stantially more direct oversight of generation resources.

In RTO regions, FERC has stepped away from direct policy oversight of wholesale electricity prices toward using markets as a tool to ensure just and reasonable prices. In these regions, generators can sell power either through bilateral contracts or through centralized electricity mar­kets administered by RTOs. 55 See Emily Hammond & David B. Spence, The Regulatory Contract in the Marketplace, 69 Vand. L. Rev. 141, 154 (2016). Markets for electricity operate on both a day-ahead and a real-time basis, with the latter market making up for any imbalances in supply and demand that occur close to the time of electricity delivery. Id. Bilateral con­tracting continues to make up a sizeable portion of electricity sales even in RTO regions. See, e.g., Collin Cain & Jonathan Lesser, Bates White Econ. Consulting, A Common Sense Guide to Wholesale Electric Markets 11 (2007), http://www.bateswhite.com/media/
publication/55_media.741.pdf
[http://perma.cc/YJ4F-PSZ3] (“Most wholesale power is bought and sold through bilat­eral contracts, freely negotiated between individual buyers and sellers. In PJM, for exam­ple, about 85% of all market sales are bilateral.”).
These are hardly “free” markets, though. FERC and the RTOs oversee these markets through a complex set of rules and agreements that establish what can be bought and sold, by whom, and how. 56 See Travis Kavulla, There Is No Free Market for Electricity: Can There Ever Be?, Am. Aff., http://americanaffairsjournal.org/2017/05/no-free-market-electricity-can-ever/ [http://perma.cc/S23A-7VGA] (last visited Apr. 16, 2018) (emphasizing how heavily regulated these markets are).

Some regions—in particular, regions in the East—have chosen to administer separate “capacity markets” to ensure that enough new gener­ation is built to serve future needs. 57 New England, New York, and PJM currently administer forward-looking capacity markets. Am. Pub. Power Ass’n, RTO Capacity Markets and Their Impacts on Consumers and Public Power 1 (2017) [hereinafter APPA, Issue Brief], http://www.publicpower.org/
system/files/documents/rto_capacity_markets_and_their_impacts_on_consumers_and_
public_power_0.pdf [http://perma.cc/AU5T-3WRV]. MISO administers a shorter-term capacity market for certain generators. See Himanshu Pande & Rachel Green, ICF Int’l, MISO’s Capacity Auction: Uncertainty Going Forward 2 (2015), http://
www.ourenergypolicy.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/05/MISO_Capacity_Auction.pdf
[http://perma.cc/8L7G-EMJ3]. FERC recently rejected a MISO proposal for a three-year forward capacity market. Midcontinent Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., Order Rejecting Tariff Filing, 158 FERC ¶ 61,128 (Feb. 2, 2017), 2017 WL 465973, at *1.
In these markets, generators 58 This Article uses “generators” for simplicity, but market participation also extends to producers of resources capable of generating “negawatts”—that is, those producers who can promise reductions in electricity demand can bid into these markets alongside supply-side generation resources. See Demand Response Compensation in Organized Wholesale Energy Markets, 76 Fed. Reg. 16,657, 16,659 (Mar. 15, 2011) (to be codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35) (requiring market operators to compensate providers of “negawatts” equally to supply-side resources); see also FERC v. Elec. Power Supply Ass’n, 136 S. Ct. 760, 773 (2016) (uphold­ing this order); Joel B. Eisen, Demand Response’s Three Generations: Market Pathways and Challenges in the Modern Electric Grid, 18 N.C. J.L. & Tech. 351, 408–09 (2017) (discussing FERC’s reasoning behind the order). bid in a promise to have available for the market a certain amount of generat­ing capacity three years in the future, and the region procures enough future capacity to meet future projected demand. 59 See N.J. Bd. of Pub. Util. v. FERC, 744 F.3d 74, 82 (3d Cir. 2014) (explaining the process by which RTOs ensure there is enough capacity “to function at peak load”). In this way, “demand” in these markets is determined by regulators’ “technocratic guesses.” Kavulla, supra note 56. In theory at least, these markets ensure long-term reliability by providing generators a second potential stream of revenue—in addition to earnings from the energy market—around which to make investment decisions. 60 Compare APPA, Issue Brief, supra note 57, at 1 (arguing that capacity markets increase prices without providing attendant benefits), with Peter Maloney, Marginal Success, Insight: U.S. Power Markets 49 (2013), http://www.platts.com/IM.Platts.
Content%5Caboutplatts%5Cmediacenter%5Cpdf%5Cinsightdec13_uspower.pdf [http://
perma.cc/7QPQ-BPUG] (arguing that capacity markets have “so far achieved their aim”).

In both energy and capacity markets, RTOs run an auction process to determine which energy resources to purchase. Generators bid in at the price they would accept, and the RTO then “stacks” these bids, “first accepting the lowest bids and then moving up and accepting higher bids until all demand [for electricity] is satisfied.” 61 Plaintiffs’ Memorandum in Opposition to Motions to Dismiss at 14, Coal. for Competitive Elec., Dynegy Inc. v. Zibelman, 272 F. Supp. 3d 554 (S.D.N.Y. 2017) (No. 16-CV-8164 (VEC)), 2017 WL 4837993, at 6; see also Elec. Power Supply Ass’n, 136 S. Ct. at 768 (“Operators accept the generators’ bids in order of cost (least expensive first) until they satisfy the [utilities’] total demand.”). All accepted bids are then paid the highest bid that “cleared” the auction. 62 See Plaintiffs’ Memorandum in Opposition to Motions to Dismiss, supra note 61, at 6; see also Brief of PJM Interconnection, LLC as Amicus Curiae in Opposition to Motions to Dismiss at 6, Elec. Power Supply Ass’n v. Star, No. 1:17-CV-01164 (N.D. Ill. Jul. 14, 2017), 2017 WL 5898038 [hereinafter PJM Amicus]. This explanation of market clear­ing is simplified. In practice, dispatch decisions also take into account where on the grid resources and demand are located, such that pricing is location specific. See Sacramento Mun. Util. Dist. v. FERC, 616 F.3d 520, 524 (D.C. Cir. 2010) (explaining locational mar­ginal pricing); Hammond & Spence, supra note 55, at 155. This “stacking” process creates incentives for generators to bid as low as they can afford to ensure that their generation clears the market and gets paid. 63 Plaintiffs’ Memorandum in Opposition to Motions to Dismiss, supra note 61; see also Hughes v. Talen Energy Mktg., LLC, 136 S. Ct. 1288, 1293–94 (2016) (“[Utilities] generally bid their capacity into the auction at a price of $0, thus guaranteeing that the capacity will clear at any price. . . . Because the fixed costs of building generating facilities often vastly exceed the variable costs of producing electricity, many generators also func­tion as price takers.”). In focus­ing solely on bid prices, the markets remain “agnostic as to resource and fuel types, so they do not favor one technology over another.” 64 PJM Amicus, supra note 62, at 7. Some suggest that the markets are less neutral in practice, because they impose certain barriers to entry on nontraditional types of resources. See, e.g., Suzanne Herel, Clean Energy Advocates Appeal FERC’s Capacity Performance Rulings, RTO Insider (July 12, 2016), http://www.rtoinsider.com/enviros-ferc-pjm-capacity-performance-28701/ [http://perma.cc/9XVK-5QRU]; see also Electric Storage Participation in Markets Operated by Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent System Operators, 81 Fed. Reg. 86,522, 86,522 (Nov. 17, 2016) (to be codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35) (proposing regulations to “remove barriers to the participa­tion of electric storage resources and distributed energy resource aggregations in the capacity, energy, and ancillary service markets operated by [RTOs and ISOs]”). Because of the efficiencies presumed to flow from this market design, FERC has declared prices established by these markets to be presumptively “just and reasonable,” such that participation in the market takes the place of the traditional requirement to file rates with FERC. 65 See Morgan Stanley Capital Grp. Inc. v. Pub. Util. Dist. No. 1, 554 U.S. 527, 535–37 (2008). More specifically, FERC has established that rates determined by the market are presumptively “just and reasonable” for any generator that it determines has “ade­quately mitigated market power, lacks the capacity to erect other barriers to entry, and has avoided giving preferences to its affiliates.” See id. at 537; see also Spence, Can Law Manage?, supra note 43, at 781.

The fact that FERC’s “wholesale” jurisdiction now revolves largely around regionally administered electricity markets 66 To be clear, FERC nominally maintains the same jurisdiction in areas of the coun­try that have not restructured. However, as was the case nationwide prerestructuring, its jurisdiction extends to fewer transactions in these regions. means that states deciding whether to join RTOs face a choice between these unusual mar­kets and more traditional regulation. 67 Note that these “markets” themselves require substantial regulatory oversight of more novel varieties. See Lester Lave et al., Deregulation/Restructuring Part I: Reregulation Will Not Fix the Problems 16 (2007), http://www.cmu.edu/gdi/docs/
deregulation-restructuring-part-i.pdf [http://perma.cc/6Q6Q-B2JY] (“The wholesale gen­eration market has not actually been deregulated or even seen less regulation. . . . If anything, there are more layers of regula­tion now.”).
States can either continue to man­age their electricity supply through government oversight and planning, or they can place their faith in regionally administered markets to deliver reliable, affordable power. States that have opted to place their faith in markets have done so believing “that it would benefit consumers by lead­ing to lower costs and lower prices in both the short run and the long run.” 68 Joskow, supra note 40, at 2; see also Blumsack, supra note 50, at 148 (“With the introduction of RTO markets, the generation resources over a number of utility control areas are cost-optimized and dispatched jointly.”).

Now, however, many of the states that chose to participate in regional markets have become increasingly aware of the limits of these markets when it comes to achieving goals beyond least-cost electricity. 69 For a thorough explanation of these limits, see generally Hammond & Spence, supra note 55 (describing the tension between market competitiveness and pursuit of environmental goals in the energy industry). Particularly with respect to climate change, which the mar­kets do not factor into their dispatch algorithms, states have had to take matters into their own hands.

B. State Climate Policies

Leading states have approached the challenge of regulating climate change with a level of commitment far beyond what would be predicted by any sort of rational-choice calculus. 70 As Professor Kirsten H. Engel has noted:
“[I]t defies economic logic that small subglobal jurisdictions, such as state and local governments in the United States, should be doing much of anything to mitigate their comparatively minor contribution to a global environmental phenomenon. Standard economic theory . . . would argue that small individual exploiters of the commons (here the global atmosphere) have little incentive to reduce the degree of their exploitation for the good of the whole in the absence of an agreement to do so that is binding on all commons users.”
Kirsten H. Engel, Mitigating Global Climate Change in the United States: A Regional Approach, 14 N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J. 54, 55 (2005).
Even as the federal government retreats on climate change, 71 See Exec. Order No. 13,783, 82 Fed. Reg. 16,093, 16,093–95 (Mar. 31, 2017) (revoking several of President Obama’s climate-related actions and ordering further review of various environmental regulations). certain states are responding bullishly. Most notably, California, New York, Massachusetts, Connecticut, Minnesota, New Jersey, Vermont, and Oregon have passed laws or promulgated exec­utive orders that establish state greenhouse gas reduction targets of between 75% and 80% by 2050. 72 Greenhouse Gas Emissions Targets, Ctr. for Climate & Energy Sols., http://
www.c2es.org/us-states-regions/policy-maps/emissions-targets
[http://perma.cc/2HCQ-T69N] (last updated Sept. 2016).
Twenty states in total have greenhouse gas targets, 73 Id. and every state has some policies in place to reduce carbon emissions. 74 See Database of State Incentives for Renewables & Efficiency, N.C. Clean Energy Tech. Ctr., http://www.dsireusa.org [http://perma.cc/65LA-3W8Q] [hereinafter DSIRE Database] (last visited Jan. 17, 2018). Although, note that in some states, policies assisting in reducing carbon pollution may not be explicitly framed around “climate change” as a goal.

Policy strategies span an enormous gamut. States are using cap-and-trade programs; 75 See Cap-and-Trade Program, Cal. Air Res. Bd., http://www.arb.ca.gov/cc/
capandtrade/capandtrade.htm
[http://perma.cc/TKN8-T4P3] (last visited Mar. 2, 2018); Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI), http://www.rggi.org [http://perma.cc/
5WNL-GG4A] [hereinafter RGGI] (last visited Jan. 17, 2018) (detailing a cap-and-trade agreement among Connecticut, Delaware, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts, New Hampshire, New York, Rhode Island, and Vermont).
renewable-energy procurement requirements; 76 See infra notes 81–98 and accompanying text. rebates and tax incentives for individuals, businesses, and communities; 77 See DSIRE Database, supra note 74 (collecting and sorting “incentives by type,” including numerous tax and other financial incentives). and novel electricity pricing schemes. 78 See, e.g., Cal. Pub. Util. Comm’n, Time of Use Rulemaking/R.15-12-012, CA.gov, http://www.cpuc.ca.gov/General.aspx?id=12180 [http://perma.cc/VT9P-YU7Z] (last visited Jan. 17, 2018) (“This effort will include development of the principles, methodolo­gies, and data sources needed to identify [time-of-use] periods that better reflect actual and near-term expected electricity supply and demand.”). In some instances, they are also considering overhauling the utility business model and the way they regulate utili­ties. 79 See Herman K. Trabish, More than 30 States Embrace Grid Modernization, New Policy Tracker Finds, Util. Dive (May 31, 2017), http://www.utilitydive.com/news/more-than-
30-states-embrace-grid-modernization-new-policy-tracker-finds/443702 [http://perma.cc/FV8S-
Y7NH].
A complete canvass of these state policies would occupy the remaining space of this Article, without contributing anything novel. 80 See Mormann, supra note 36, at 1625 (describing how “[i]n the absence of com­prehensive federal policy action on climate change and clean energy, states are increas­ingly stepping in to fill the policy void” (footnote omitted)). For examples of state climate policies, see David R. Hodas, State Initiatives, in Global Climate Change and U.S. Law 303 (Michael B. Gerrard & Jody Freeman eds., 2d ed. 2014) (providing an overview of state initiatives adopted to address climate change, “explicitly or indirectly through energy regulation, transportation-related initiatives, or energy building codes”); Rossi, Carbon Taxation, supra note 8, at 279–80 (explaining how states use traditional utility regulation, specifically customer rate subsidies in energy law, to advance carbon reduction goals). See generally Lincoln L. Davies, Reconciling Renewable Portfolio Standards and Feed-In Tariffs, 32 Utah Envtl. L. Rev. 311 (2012) [hereinafter Davies, Reconciling] (arguing states should blend both renewable portfolio standards and feed-in tariffs in designing their renewable-energy policies). Instead, this section examines three popular state climate policies that have been the most controversial for the ways in which they intersect with regional electricity markets: renewable portfolio standards, direct pro­curement orders, and “zero-emissions credits” for nuclear generators.

Renewable Portfolio Standards (RPSs) are one of the most popular state tools for promoting low-carbon energy sources. Twenty-nine states currently have an RPS in place. 81 Renewable Portfolio Standard Policies, Database of State Incentives for Renewables & Efficiency, N.C. Clean Energy Tech. Ctr. (2017) [hereinafter Renewable Portfolio Standard Policies], http://ncsolarcen-prod.s3.amazonaws.com/wp-content/uploads/
2017/03/Renewable-Portfolio-Standards.pdf
[http://perma.cc/6ZMN-GZEE].
These laws require 82 Eight additional states have renewable portfolio “goals” but not requirements. Id. utilities in the state to source a certain percentage of the electricity that they sell from renew­able sources by a certain date. 83 Mormann, supra note 36, at 1624. In some cases, state law specifies an absolute quantity. See, e.g., Renewable Portfolio Standard Policies, supra note 81 (showing Texas with an RPS of 5,880 megawatts by 2015). This approach enables utilities to seek out the cheapest renewable energy available to satisfy the state mandate. 84 Lincoln L. Davies, Power Forward: The Argument for a National RPS, 42 Conn. L. Rev. 1339, 1357 (2010) [hereinafter Davies, Power Forward]. Typically, states track compliance with their RPS by issuing “Renewable Energy Credits” (RECs) to renewable energy generators, which utilities then purchase to prove that the requisite share of their energy has come from renewable sources. 85 Id. at 1359–60; see also Todd Jones et al., Ctr. for Res. Sols., The Legal Basis for Renewable Energy Certificates 3 (2015) (“Thirty-six (36) U.S. states and territories recog­nize that RECs can be used to track and transact renewable electricity on the grid.”). REC trading is often limited to either in-state or in-region. Cf. Robin Kundis Craig, Constitutional Contours for the Design and Implementation of Multistate Renewable Energy Programs and Projects, 81 U. Colo. L. Rev. 771, 795 (2010) (“[A]t the state level, RPS requirements that favor instate RECs or forbid out-of-state RECs could run afoul of the dormant Commerce Clause. Similarly, multistate agreements that allow REC trading within the consortium but prohibit RECs from other states could raise constitutional concerns.”). RECs thus help create a more liquid market for renewable energy by allowing the “renewable” attribute to be sold separately from the underlying energy. 86 Joel H. Mack et al., All RECs Are Local: How In-State Generation Requirements Adversely Affect Development of a Robust REC Market, Elec. J., May 2011, at 8, 10; see also Allco Fin. Ltd. v. Klee, 861 F.3d 82, 92–93 (2d Cir. 2017) (explaining RECs); Kelly Crandall, Comment, Trust and the Green Consumer: The Fight for Accountability in Renewable Energy Credits, 81 U. Colo. L. Rev. 893, 904 (2010) (same). FERC has explicitly endorsed the existence of RECs as creations of state law that can legally exist apart from the underlying electricity bought and sold. See WSPP Inc., 139 FERC ¶ 61,061 (Apr. 20, 2012), 2012 WL 1395532, at *5.

In the most ambitious states, RPSs require a substantial percentage of renewables: In New York and California, this percentage is 50% by 2030; in Vermont, 75% by 2032. 87 Renewable Portfolio Standard Policies, supra note 81. Direct comparison of these standards can be challenging—one must know precisely what resources are included, whether or not renewables that existed before passage of the RPS are included, and what the natural resource endowment of the state is like. See Davies, Power Forward, supra note 84, at 1361. In 2015, Hawaii adopted a 100% target by 2045. 88 Act of June 8, 2015, 2015 Haw. Sess. Laws 245; see also Renewable Portfolio Standard Policies, supra note 81; About the Hawaii Clean Energy Initiative, http://
www.hawaiicleanenergyinitiative.org/about-the-hawaii-clean-energy-initiative [http://
perma.cc/QG3D-NVFP] (last visited Jan. 18, 2018).
In total, state RPS policies have driven more than half the growth in U.S. renewable energy generation to date and are expected to drive another 50% growth in the sector by 2030—making them an enor­mously important state climate policy. 89 Galen Barbose, Lawrence Berkeley Nat’l Lab., U.S. Renewables Portfolio Standards: 2016 Annual Status Report 2 (2016), http://emp.lbl.gov/sites/all/files/lbnl-1005057.pdf [http://perma.cc/D55H-V9VS].

Each state RPS defines qualifying renewable resources in its own way, sometimes by enumerating a list, 90 See, e.g., In re Retail Renewable Portfolio Standard, 235 Pub. Util. Rep. 4th (PUR) 414 (N.Y. Pub. Serv. Comm’n 2004) (defining eligible resources as biogas (including anaerobic digestion and landfill gas), biomass, fuel cells, hydro (without new storage impoundment), solar, tidal/ocean, and wind). and other times more conceptually. For example, Vermont’s definition of renewables includes any “technol­ogy that relies on a resource that is being consumed at a harvest rate at or below its natural regeneration rate.” 91 Vt. Stat. Ann. tit. 30, § 8002(21) (2016). Some states use these schemes to express more idiosyncratic preferences tailored to local conditions. 92 See Davies, Power Forward, supra note 84, at 1360–62 (discussing differences in terms of four core RPS design traits); Steven Ferrey et al., Fire and Ice: World Renewable Energy and Carbon Control Mechanisms Confront Constitutional Barriers, 20 Duke Envtl. L. & Pol’y F. 125, 144–50 (2010) (cataloguing different state RPSs). Maryland, for instance, includes electricity produced from chicken manure in its RPS, while North Carolina includes electricity from hog waste. 93 See Md. Code Ann., Pub. Util. § 7-701(j), (m) (LexisNexis 2016) (defining poul­try litter, which is used in thermal biomass systems); N.C. Gen. Stat. § 62-133.8(e) (2015) (establishing a specific requirement for swine waste). Numerous states also establish “tiers” or “carve-outs” within their RPSs, which mandate a certain amount of the overall requirement to come from particular resource types. Twenty-two of the twenty-nine states with RPSs have a carve-out relating either to solar energy or “distributed gener­ation”—a term used to describe small-scale generating resources located at or near the site of consumption. 94 Renewable Portfolio Standards (RPS) with Solar or Distributed Generation Provisions, Database of State Incentives for Renewables & Efficiency, N.C. Clean Energy Tech. Ctr. (2017), http://ncsolarcen-prod.s3.amazonaws.com/wp-content/uploads/2017/
02/RPS_carveout_4.pdf
[http://perma.cc/EYJ9-QEAV] (mapping which states have solar- or distributed-generation provisions).

In some states, legislatures have created additional procurement processes for certain clean-energy resources above and beyond the RPS. 95 Two recent articles clarify why a state might layer procurement policies on top of an RPS. See Davies, Reconciling, supra note 80, at 313 (discussing how RPSs and other incen­tives can complement each other); Mormann, supra note 36, at 1658–59 (proposing a model for integrating RPSs and feed-in tariffs). As Davies and Mormann explain, RPS and procurement policies can be blended to create, on the one hand, substantial demand for renewable energy and, on the other hand, assurance to investors of certain returns over a longer period of time. Davies, Reconciling, supra note 80, at 314; Mormann, supra note 36, at 1628. For example, in 2016, Massachusetts passed “An Act Relative to Energy Diversity,” which requires utilities in the state to enter into long-term con­tracts for 1,600 megawatts of offshore wind energy. 96 An Act to Promote Energy Diversity, 2016 Mass. Acts, http://malegislature.gov/
Laws/SessionLaws/Acts/2016/Chapter188
[http://perma.cc/53RC-PJWA] (last visited Apr. 4, 2018). Some states alternatively include a carve-out for offshore wind within their RPS. Benjamin Storrow, Mid-Atlantic Enters “Offshore Game” in a Big Way, ClimateWire (May 12, 2017), http://www.eenews.net/climatewire/2017/05/12/stories/1060054457 (on file with the Columbia Law Review).
The state has also joined California in mandating that utilities acquire a certain amount of energy-storage resources. 97 Cal. Pub. Utils. Comm’n, Rulemaking No. 10-12-007, Decision Adopting Energy Storage Procurement Framework and Design Program (2013); Peter Maloney, Massachusetts DOER Will Set Energy Storage Mandate Targets by July, Util. Dive (Jan. 3, 2017), http://www.utilitydive.com/news/massachusetts-doer-will-set-energy-storage-mandate-
targets-by-july/433138/
[http://perma.cc/PB9Q-XD32].
Several other northeastern states also have special procurement processes for additional renewable resources. 98 See infra note 264 (gathering cases explaining and evaluating these policies).

Finally, there is perhaps the most controversial policy of them all: state support for particular nuclear plants at risk of retiring. New York pioneered this strategy with its Public Service Commission’s 2016 decision to provide payments, per megawatt hour, to three nuclear units in New York State that it determined were at risk of retiring without state aid. 99 See N.Y. Pub. Serv. Comm’n, Proceeding on Motion of the Comm’n to Implement a Large-Scale Renewable Program & a Clean Energy Standard, 331 Pub. Util. Rep. 4th (PUR) 357 (Aug. 1, 2016) [hereinafter Clean Energy Standard Order] (on file with the Columbia Law Review). The state awards these units “Zero-Emission Credits” (ZECs) for each megawatt hour of energy they produce through the year 2029. 100 Id. at 144–45. New York utilities are required to purchase these ZECs, with their price determined by the “Social Cost of Carbon”—a figure calculated by the Obama Administration. 101 Id. at 149–50. President Trump has since withdrawn the findings of the Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Greenhouse Gases, describing them as “no longer representative of governmental policy.” Exec. Order No. 13,783, 82 Fed. Reg. 16,093, 16,093–95 (Mar. 31, 2017). The ZEC price for the first two years of the program is around $17.50 per megawatt hour; after that time, the ZEC price may decline based on forecasted prices in wholesale markets. 102 Clean Energy Standard Order, supra note 99, at 51.

Several states have either followed or are considering following simi­lar courses. Illinois adopted a ZEC program in December 2016, which looks quite similar to New York’s. 103 See 20 Ill. Comp. Stat. Ann. 3855/1–75(d–5) (West Supp. 2017); id. at 3855/1–10; State Defendants’ Memorandum in Support of Motion to Dismiss at 6, Elec. Power Supply Ass’n v. Star, No. 1:17-CV-01164 (N.D. Ill. Jul. 14, 2017), 2017 WL 5898040 (describ­ing Illinois’s program). Both states have quickly faced law­suits challenging the legality of the programs under the Federal Power Act’s framework of shared federal–state jurisdiction. 104 See infra notes 251–257 and accompanying text. The lawsuits have not, however, deterred Connecticut, Ohio, Pennsylvania, and New Jersey from seeking to enact similar programs. 105 Ken Dixon, Malloy Signs Millstone Nuclear Bill, Conn. Post (Oct. 31, 2017), http://www.ctpost.com/local/article/Malloy-signs-Millstone-nuclear-bill-12320251.php [http://perma.cc/5UX9-MJLU]; Marie Cusick, Lawmakers Mull Support for Nuclear Industry, NPR: StateImpact Pa. (Apr. 26, 2017), http://stateimpact.npr.org/pennsylvania/
2017/04/26/lawmakers-mull-support-for-nuclear-industry [http://perma.cc/7BX2-2JBD]; Peter Maloney, Ohio Lawmakers Introduce Bill To Support FirstEnergy’s Nuclear Plants, Util. Dive (Apr. 6, 2017), http://www.utilitydive.com/news/ohio-lawmakers-introduce-bill-to-support-firstenergys-nuclear-plants/439950/ [http://perma.cc/MF5F-EF6D].

Altogether, the suite of policies that states have amassed to meet their decarbonization goals is both impressive and eclectic—to some delightfully so; to others, frustratingly so. 106 See infra section I.C (explaining the divergent viewpoints on the advisability of these state policies). In the next Part, this Article analyzes and defends these diverse climate policies and the preferences they represent. First, though, it is helpful to understand the problems that detractors believe these state policies present to regional electricity markets.

C. Tensions at the Intersection

State climate policies and regional electricity markets have coex­isted—and indeed, grown together—for around two decades. 107 See Tierney, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 52, at 2 (observing the prev­alence of state policies that can affect wholesale market prices); see also Robert Klee, Comm’r, Conn. Dep’t of Energy & Envtl. Prot., Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 1 (May 1–2, 2017), http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170426145943-Klee,%20Connecticut%20DEEP.pdf [http://perma.cc/9CVL-GM3C] (noting that in 1998, Connecticut enacted clean-energy policies contemporaneously with legislation deregulat­ing electricity). Why the recent fuss? Regional market operator PJM—an RTO that spans the mid-Atlantic—offers perhaps the most parsimonious explanation for the present spate of concern: “Subsidies are contagious.” 108 Monitoring Analytics, LLC, State of the Market Report for PJM, Volume 2: Detailed Analysis 2 (2017) [hereinafter Monitoring Analytics, State of the Market Report], http://www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/PJM_State_of_the_Market/2016/2016-som-pjm-volume2.pdf [http://perma.cc/UAJ9-YY3A]. By “subsidies,” PJM is ref­erencing the myriad state policies detailed above that help pro­mote various clean-energy resources. As this quote suggests, regional electricity-market operators are nervous about the proliferation of these state-level, resource-specific policies as a means to achieve ambitious climate-mitigation goals.

The first common complaint about these state policies is that pay­ments to specific zero-carbon resources unfairly suppress market prices. For example, plaintiffs suing to contest the legality of New York’s ZEC program explain their concerns as follows: Providing existing nuclear units an out-of-market ZEC payment enables these nuclear plants to lower the price at which they bid into the market. 109 See Complaint at 19–23, Coal. for Competitive Elec. v. Zibelman, 272 F. Supp. 3d 554 (S.D.N.Y. 2017) (No. 16-CV-8164 (VEC))(describing New York’s subsidy scheme); see also Robert C. Flexon, President & CEO, Dynegy Inc., Pre-Conference Remarks at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 2 (May 1–2, 2017) [hereinafter Dynegy, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170426151233-Flexon,%20Dynegy.pdf [http:// perma.cc/CV5N-L53M] (“In RTO/ISO markets, a generator relies on the com­bination of energy and capacity revenues to recover its costs. A generator’s offer to supply energy and/or capacity is typically tied to its cost[s] . . . the ZECs will enable the nuclear generators to make offers well below their production costs.”). Then, the clearing price of the entire market is lowered such that other plants that do not receive subsidies either fail to clear the auctions or clear at a lower price. Consequently, the argument goes, “the ZEC program . . . distorts the functioning of the FERC-regulated energy and capacity markets.” 110 Plaintiffs’ Memorandum in Opposition to Motions to Dismiss, supra note 61, at 7. Sim­ilar complaints extend to other state support policies, such as RPS and specific procurement policies, which some believe “cause a similar type of harm to . . . markets.” 111 PJM Amicus, supra note 62, at 9.

Perhaps the most contested element of this narrative is the norma­tive claim that the market is “distorted” and “harmed,” rather than merely altered, by these kinds of state policies. An alternative view is that it is perfectly legitimate for states to support certain resources and that such support does not render these resources’ market bids “uneco­nomic.” 112 Jennifer Chen, Sustainable FERC Project, Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 2 (May 1–2, 2017) [hereinafter Chen, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/
CalendarFiles/20170426151027-Chen,%20Natural%20Resources%20
Defense%20Council.pdf [http://perma.cc/9T47-PNA5]; see also Lisa G. McAlister, Am. Mun. Power, Pre-Conference Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 3 (May 1–2, 2017) [hereinafter American Municipal Power, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/
20170426151448-McAlister,%20American%20Municipal%20Power.pdf [http://perma.cc/
NAU5-EHMY] (“An effort to distinguish between state actions that are ‘inside’ versus ‘outside’ the market would be misplaced.”).
To the contrary, this view holds, state support policies are per­missible judgment calls by states that exist at “the heart of their historic juris­diction over generation resources.” 113 Robert Erwin, Gen. Counsel, Md. Pub. Serv. Comm’n, Comments at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 4 (May 1–2, 2017) [hereinafter Erwin, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170426150720-Erwin,%20Maryland%20PSC.pdf [http://perma.cc/PQR3-KQJD]. If they affect market prices, so be it—there’s nothing necessarily wrong with that. Indeed, subsidies to fossil fuels have long affected their relative competitiveness in ways that the market has not accounted for. 114 See Rossi, Carbon Taxation, note 8, at 287 n.49 (“Studies that incorporate envi­ronmental and energy security costs associated with fossil fuels in the United States esti­mate that annual direct and indirect subsidies exceed $121 billion (in 1999 dollars).”).

Moving beyond these semantics—and the substantially different views they represent of the relative hierarchy of market functioning and state policy goals—can be challenging. Complaints about state clean-energy policies lowering market prices often feel like their own protec­tionist effort to insulate carbon-heavy resources from necessary change. But the most compelling version of this argument looks further down the road than mere market “distortion.” That longer-term argument pro­ceeds like this: States decided to join regional electricity markets to have these markets competitively select least-cost electricity and generating capacity. Going forward, states plan to continue to rely on these markets to send signals about whether and when to invest in new generating capacity in any particular region. But if state policies in support of cer­tain resources lower the prices those markets are sending to everyone else, then it may well be the case that non-policy-supported generators—in particular, natural gas generators 115 See Paul Hibbard et al., Analysis Grp., Electricity Markets, Reliability and the Evolving U.S. Power System 15 (2017) (noting combined-cycle, natural gas combustion turbines are “the technology of choice for new fossil-fueled generation investment in most regions”); see also Raymond L. Gifford et al., The Breakdown of the Merchant Generation Business Model: A Clear-Eyed View of Risks and Realities Facing Merchants 7 exh.6 (2017) [hereinafter Gifford et al., Merchant Report]. —no longer see value in building new plants. 116 See, e.g., ISO New England Inc. Pre-Conference Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 1 (May 1–2, 2017) [hereinafter ISO-NE, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/
CalendarFiles/20170426150054-White,%20ISO-NE.pdf
[http://perma.cc/U6S8-GRVL] (suggesting that subsidized “out-of-market procurements could undermine cost-effective price formation, in turn impacting both [the ISO-NE capacity market’s] ability to attract unsubsidized new investment cost effectively and inves­tors’ willingness to maintain existing supply resources”); see also NRG Power Mktg., LLC v. FERC, 862 F.3d 108, 111 (D.C. Cir. 2017) (observing that these challenges could ultimately lead to “brownouts or blackouts”); Gifford et al., Merchant Report, supra note 115, at 1; ISO New England, 2016 Economic Study: NEPOOL Scenario Analysis (First Draft) 5 (2017) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (“New resources will require sources of revenue in addition to the wholesale energy market to remain economically viable. Natural gas units show the greatest revenue shortfall [because] of their production costs being higher than the $0/MWh fuel costs of renewables, but renewable resources also show significant revenue shortfalls.”).

This result, in and of itself, might be exactly what states desire: Their policies push out existing, carbon-emitting resources by supporting cer­tain zero-carbon resources. But here’s where PJM’s worry about subsidies’ contagiousness comes into play: Renewable energy, nuclear energy, and natural gas have different attributes that lead them not to be perfectly interchangeable electricity sources. Solar and wind energy are available only when the sun is shining or the wind is blowing, respectively. Nuclear power cannot be turned on and off quickly—meaning that it is not very useful in balancing out the variability in solar and wind. 117 See MIT, The Future of the Electric Grid: An Interdisciplinary MIT Study 53–76 (2011) (discussing the challenges of depending upon variable energy sources). Natural gas and hydropower, by contrast, are capable of quickly “ramping” up and down, such that they act as flexible complements to these variable resources. 118 Id. at 64; see also Hammond & Spence, supra note 55, at 164. Electricity storage can play a similar role in “smoothing” out electricity supply. 119 See Judy W. Chang et al., Brattle Grp., Advancing Past “Baseload” to a Flexible Grid: How Grid Planners and Power Markets Are Better Defining System Needs to Achieve a Cost-Effective and Reliable Supply Mix 17 (2017), http://files.brattle.com/files/7352_
advancing_past_baseload_to_a_flexible_grid.pdf
[http://perma.cc/FS9T-RZV6] (explaining the role that “flexible resources” can play in “help[ing] to integrate variable renewable resources”); Amy L. Stein, Reconsidering Regulatory Uncertainty: Making a Case for Energy Storage, 41 Fla. St. U. L. Rev. 697, 710–12 (2014) (“[R]eliability benefits can come in the form of backup electricity in times of power outages, enhanced power quality to prevent outage, and frequency regulation that adjusts for differences between grid operators’ predictions and actual demand.”).

These divergent characteristics underpin the “contagion” worry. As renewable energy comes to play a larger role in the grid, states may realize that they need a certain amount of natural gas, electricity storage, or some other new resource to keep their decarboniz­ing grid running smoothly and efficiently. 120 Cf. Abraham Silverman, Deputy Gen. Counsel & Vice President, Regulatory, at NRG Energy, Inc., Pre-Technical Conference Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 2 (May 1–2, 2017) [hereinafter NRG Energy, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/
20170426151513-Silverman,%20NRG.pdf [http://perma.cc/6M75-V8AE] (explain­ing that to succeed in decarbonizing the grid, “the power sector must be ruthlessly efficient in attracting and deploying capital”).
In this case, if the market is incapable of supporting such resources, states may end up having to also design subsidy programs for these resources. 121 See Michael Hogan, Regulatory Assistance Project (RAP), Hitting the Mark on Missing Money: How to Ensure Reliability at Least Cost to Consumers 7 (2016), http://www.raponline.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/09/rap-hogan-hitting-mark-missing-money-2016-september.pdf [http://perma.cc/QGG6-9YWU] (explaining that markets increasingly will need flexible resources as renewables’ penetration increases and that these flexible resources are missing the necessary “remuneration of investment”); Monitoring Analytics, State of the Market Report, supra note 108, at 2 (providing detailed analytics assessing proposed subsidy solutions); David B. Spence, Paradoxes of “Decarbonization,” 82 Brook. L. Rev. 447, 470 (2017) [hereinafter Spence, Paradoxes] (observing that a recognition that natural gas will be a necessary backup fuel on an all-renewables grid “begs the question[] [of] who will own and build natural gas-fired power plants that will almost never be used”). Eventually, the market might be so poor at sending competitive price signals that the only way for any resource to remain viable 122 Emily Hammond and David Spence do an excellent job explaining why market prices may fail to provide adequate returns on investment to plant owners. See Spence & Hammond, supra note 55, at 163. would be to obtain state subsidies. 123 See PJM Amicus, supra note 62, at 8 (“Lower clearing prices . . . starve otherwise economic existing generation, beginning a vicious cycle that requires these plants also to look for out-of-market subsidies, further depressing clearing prices and undermining the market price.”). Such a result would ultimately amount to creeping, accidental re-regulation of the electricity sector and abandonment of the gains states intended to obtain from regional electricity markets. 124 See Dynegy, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 109, at 5 (explaining that “[r]ecent state-level interventions have had a devastating effect on the ability of unsubsi­dized market participants to attract and retain private capital”); Tierney, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 52, at 6 (suggesting this result would “affect the continuing viabil­ity of the current designs of these three RTOs’ forward capacity markets”); Gavin Bade, Re-Regulation on the Horizon? State Plant Subsidies Point to Looming ‘Crisis’ in Organized Power Markets, Util. Dive (Oct. 20, 2016), http://www.utilitydive.com/news/re-regulation-vertically-integrated-utility/428639/ [http://perma.cc/YG54-HDR8] (arguing that “[w]ithout concerted action to alter market constructs . . . states will turn back to a vertically-integrated utility model”). Indeed, one might interpret DOE’s NOPR proposing cost-of-service ratemaking for fuel-secure resources as a glaring example of precisely this type of “creeping subsidy.” See Grid Resiliency Pricing Rule, 82 Fed. Reg. 46,940 (proposed Oct. 10, 2017) (to be codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35).

Whether this potentiality presents an imminent threat remains a matter of debate. For the moment, the worry is particularly acute in the eastern RTOs that rely on regional forward capacity markets as the pri­mary way to ensure resource adequacy (that is, enough electricity going for­ward to keep the lights on). In these regions, states have largely required utilities to sell off their generation assets, such that corporations building generators do not have the benefit of a captive monopoly rate base 125 In regulated regions, approved capital expenditures make up a utility’s “rate base.” The utility is entitled to recover the costs reflected in the rate base as well as a reason­able rate of return, typically around ten percent per year. See Fed. Power Comm’n v. Hope Nat. Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 602–03 (1944) (establishing the governing standard for whether rates are “just and reasonable”); see also Edison Elec. Inst., Q4 2015 Rate Case Summary 1 (2016), http://www.eei.org/resourcesandmedia/industrydataanalysis/industryfinancialanalysis/
QtrlyFinancialUpdates/Documents/QFU_Rate_Case/2015_Q4_Rate_Case.pdf [http://
perma.cc/QK53-SV8K] (finding that the average return on equity in the fourth quarter of 2015 was 9.62%, “a near-record low in . . . over-three-decades of data”).
to help pay for new plants. 126 In other RTOs, states maintain a more direct role in ensuring resource adequacy by approving certain generation resources for construction and assuring utilities a fair rate of return on these assets. See PJM Amicus, supra note 62, at 3 (explaining these regional differences); Spence, Paradoxes, supra note 121, at 464–65 (arguing the “problem of attracting private capital lies at the heart of public utility regulation, and hangs like a shadow over hybrid and competitive markets”); Tierney, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 52, at 2–3 (explaining why regions where states maintain a traditionally regu­lated utility industry are less impacted by these concerns). Instead, these generators rely exclu­sively on payments from electricity markets as the way to recoup their investments, such that a depression in market prices threatens their survival to a greater extent than in other markets.

Although state reregulation of the electricity sector is sometimes held out as a plausible solution to these challenges, no state pursuing aggressive decarbonization expresses reregulation as its aim. 127 LaFleur, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 16, at 54–55 (summarizing the view of state representatives, who “in general still want the centralized market to play some role in resources for liability and sustaining existing resources for reliability” and who were not “going to take over buying all the resources at the state level”). Instead, states wish to remain a part of regional electricity markets while also accomplishing their decarbonization goals. 128 See ISO-NE, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 116, at 1 (explaining that “New England states have not expressed interest” in returning to a situation in which they fully control resource adequacy); see also Susanne Desroches, Deputy Dir., Infrastructure Policy, N.Y.C. Mayor’s Office of Recovery and Resiliency, Pre-Conference Comments at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 5 (Apr. 25, 2017), http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170426150357-DesRoches,%20New%20York%20City.pdf [http://perma.cc/68CN-FEX4] (“To be clear, the City continues to see value in the wholesale markets, and it is not suggesting that we go back to vertically integrated utilities.”). Accordingly, the key question becomes how to balance the aims of these policies with the risks they present to electricity-market functionality. Before taking up this question in Parts III and IV, the next Part argues that the answer to this question requires a deeper understanding of the nature of the project of decar­bonization—an understanding that has largely been lacking in conversa­tions to date. 129 See Roopali Phadke, Public Deliberation and the Geographies of Wind Justice, 22 Sci. as Culture 247, 248 (2013) (“To date, new energy policy has focused on innovation and investment pipelines. Remarkably, little attention has been paid to understanding the social dimensions of these major infrastructure shifts.”).

II. What Should We Ask of Decarbonization? Preferences Beyond Least Cost

At one level, decarbonization is a technical challenge. To combat climate change, the amount of carbon released in the production of elec­tricity must be dramatically reduced. Leading studies suggest that ade­quately mitigating climate change—that is, minimizing the possibility of planetary catastrophe—will require “deep decarbonization” of developed country economies. 130 The White House, United States Mid-Century Strategy for Deep Decarbonization 6–7 (2016), http://unfccc.int/files/focus/long-term_strategies/application/pdf/mid_century_
strategy_report-final_red.pdf [http://perma.cc/DH3A-7YTM]; Williams et al., Deep Decarbonization Policy, supra note 6, at 11; see also John C. Dernbach, Pathways to a Zero-Carbon Future, Envtl. F., July–Aug. 2017, at 30, 35.
“Deep decarbonization” in this context describes decarbonization efforts of around 80% by 2050—precisely the aim embraced by leading U.S. states. 131 Williams et al., Deep Decarbonization Policy, supra note 6, at 35.

Several recent projects have fleshed out the technological changes nec­essary to accomplish this transformation. These projects yield answers along the following lines: “The carbon intensity of electricity will need to be reduced by a startling 97%.” 132 Id. at 49. To do so, “[p]etroleum, coal, and natu­ral gas [must] play a much smaller role in the primary energy supply,” and “wind, solar, biomass, and nuclear [must] become the dominant share of primary energy supply.” 133 Id. at 19–20. These changes will, of course, “pro­foundly transform the U.S. energy economy.” 134 Id. at 9. A more interesting and open question, though, is how—and how much—these major infrastruc­ture changes will reverberate throughout the American economy and American society.

A. Two Visions of the Decarbonized Future

It can be difficult to trace the ways in which discrete energy-infra­structure decisions affect larger social and political structures. It is often only in hindsight, after the gradual accretion of decades of such decisions, that we can understand how energy policies interrelate to larger ques­tions of social structure and economic and political power. 135 For a powerful demonstration of these interlinkages, see generally Timothy Mitchell, Carbon Democracy: Political Power in the Age of Oil (2011), which traces the ways in which the switch from coal to oil as a dominant fuel impacted political economy and political institutions in the Western world. But part of this Article’s argument is that it is important to appreciate up front—as best we can—the expansive effects that our choices around how to decarbonize the energy system are likely to have.

In an attempt to develop an appreciation of decarbonization’s potentially widespread ramifications, this section asks the reader to con­sider two divergent pathways to deep decarbonization. The first emerges from a recent, personal conversation with an acquaintance who works for a major environmental not-for-profit that will remain undisclosed. 136 That makes this anecdote hard to cite. But it is not particularly important that it can be externally validated—it is offered in the spirit of exploring “sociotechnical imagi­naries,” as described by the scholar of science, technology, and society, Professor Sheila Jasanoff. Sheila Jasanoff & Sang-Hyun Kim, Sociotechnical Imaginaries and National Energy Policies, 22 Sci. as Culture 189, 190 (2013). These imaginaries, for Jasanoff, are “‘collectively imagined forms of social life and social order reflected in the design and fulfillment of nation-specific scientific and/or technological projects,’” as well as “powerful cultural resources that help shape social responses to innovation.” Id. (quoting Sheila Jasanoff and Sang-Hyun Kim, Containing the Atom: Sociotechnical Imaginaries and Nuclear Power in the United States and South Korea, 47 Minerva 119, 120 (2009)); see also Charles Taylor, Modern Social Imaginaries 23 (2004) (defining “social imaginaries” as “the ways people imagine their social existence, how they fit together with others, how things go on between them and their fellows, the expectations that are normally met, and the deeper normative notions and images that underlie these expectations”). He explained that, frustrated with recent backsliding on climate change in the United States, his organization was quietly assembling a group of the major fossil fuel companies in an attempt to devise a response to climate change that would ensure that the companies maintained their domi­nant role in the economy. That is to say, this group hoped to draft legisla­tion related to decarbonization that would do as little as possible to shake up market shares, or political power, within the energy industry or beyond. In this group’s view, accepting a policy actively designed to fore­stall any significant distributional shifts is the surest way to achieve rapid deep decarbonization.

If this pathway were taken, the major political and economic players in the decarbonized future might not look so different from those of today—many of the changes would play out behind the scenes of the electricity grid. All of us would get used to landscapes dotted by major utility-scale wind farms, nuclear power plants, solar arrays, and transmis­sion lines, owned by companies like Exxon and BP. 137 Several of the big oil companies are already moving in this direction. See, e.g., Anna Hirtenstein, Big Oil Follows Silicon Valley into Backing Green Energy Firms, Bloomberg Tech. (Aug. 15, 2017), http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-08-15/big-oil-follows-silicon-valley-into-backing-green-energy-firms/ [http://perma.cc/XKT9-3FFV]. Companies would build whichever combination of these resources proved most profitable to them. The price of electricity would likely rise, but companies such as General Electric would provide new technologies to help control electric­ity demand—technologies that would be available to those who could afford them. 138 See Shelley Welton, Clean Electrification, 88 U. Colo. L. Rev. 571, 591–609 (2017) (exploring the trend toward creating a “participatory grid” and the equity challenges it presents).

Now, consider a second, quite different pathway that a country or state could take toward decarbonization. This pathway emerges from the thesis of journalist Naomi Klein’s 2014 book This Changes Everything. 139 Naomi Klein, This Changes Everything: Capitalism vs. The Climate (2014). In her view, the reason that the world has made so little progress on climate change is that “the Right is Right”: Addressing climate change requires actions that “directly challenge our reigning economic paradigm” and “spell extinction for the richest and most powerful industry the world has ever known—the oil and gas industry.” 140 Id. at 31, 63. She doubts that any significant solution can be forged through cooperation with major corporations, citing the poor record of this strategy to date. 141 Id. at 207–49. Instead, she sees the challenge of climate change as an opportunity to forge new grassroots alliances that link climate change to community health and that demand more democratic decisionmaking and local economic power. 142 See id. at 96–97, 360–61. Climate change, in this view, “could be the catalyst to attack inequality at its core.” 143 Id. at 409.

If this pathway toward decarbonization were pursued, there might be an efflorescence of city movements to reclaim their electricity grids from private ownership. 144 See Shelley Welton, Public Energy, 92 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 267, 304–07 (2017) [hereinafter Welton, Public Energy] (documenting efforts in this vein). Communities would collectively invest in locally sited solar and wind farms, deciding to pay more to support local clean energy and local jobs. Consumption of energy and other goods might fall as the country pursued low-growth economic policies that focused on delivering free time instead of material accumulation, in an effort to spread fewer resources more broadly. 145 See, e.g., Tim Jackson, Prosperity Without Growth: Economics for a Finite Planet 3, 151, 180 (2011) (asking “[w]hat can prosperity possibly look like in a finite world” and concluding that it might include consuming less, improving social equality, and working fewer hours). Significant lifestyle changes might be required, including reduced consumption of meat and dairy, less car ownership, and fewer airplane trips. 146 See Mike Childs, Friends of the Earth, Just Transition: Is a Just Transition to a Low-Carbon Economy Possible Within Safe Global Carbon Limits? 4 (2011), http://
friendsoftheearth.uk/sites/default/files/downloads/just_transition.pdf
[http://perma.cc/
H77H-FXET] (finding these sacrifices necessary if the United Kingdom were to meet decarbonization goals while ensuring that “essential needs for housing, transport and energy use are met”).

It is hard to get much further apart than these two visions of the decarbonized future—one based entirely on political expediency and maintenance of the economic order; the other based on a vision of using the project of decarbonization to radically restructure political and social relations. Their coexistence hints at the range of possibilities that decar­bonization holds for power structures, community character, and daily life. No matter how we approach it, decarbonization will shape more than just physical infrastructure, making it a social project as much as a technical one.

There is considerably more to be said about the many contours of the “social project” of decarbonization, but much of it will have to wait for future work. This Article does not attempt to explore the range of potential considerations or solutions in their entirety, nor does it make any judgment about the most viable or desirable version of this social project. For the present argument, it is enough to understand that decar­bonization is, inexorably, more than just a technical challenge. Discus­sions around its trajectory implicate choices and values that extend far beyond what technologies are available at what costs. 147 Many scholars outside the legal field have forcefully made similar points. See, e.g., Govert Valkenburg & Giancarlo Cotella, Governance of Energy Transitions: About Inclusion and Closure in Complex Sociotechnical Problems, 6 Energy Sustainability & Soc’y (2016), http://link.springer.com/content/pdf/10.1186%2Fs13705-016-0086-8.pdf [http://perma.cc/R7LH-KET4] (describing the energy transition as “at once a tech­nological, regulation and political problem” that implicates a “heterogeneity of relevant values”); Catherine Butler et al., Public Values for Energy Futures: Framing, Indeterminacy and Policy Making, 87 Energy Pol’y 665, 669 (2015) [hereinafter Butler et al., Public Values] (finding that the public “situate[s] climate change as just one element within a much wider set of concerns about environment and human/nature relations”); Christina Demski et al., Public Values for Energy System Change, 34 Global Envtl. Change 59, 59 (2015) (“Publics are deeply implicated in energy transitions, for example as con­sumers and producers of energy, as citizens with voting powers, or as active protesters and proponents of energy infrastructures.”); Jasanoff & Kim, supra note 136, at 189 (“[R]adical changes in the fuel supply are likely to transform social infrastructures, chang­ing established patterns of life and work and allocating benefits and burdens differently from before.”); Clark A. Miller & Jennifer Richter, Social Planning for Energy Transitions, 1 Current Sustainable Renewable Energy Rep. 77, 78 (2014) (“[T]he rise of new energy resources (or the end of old ones) can give rise to massive reconfiguration of social, envi­ronmental, and technological landscapes . . . .”); Andre Silveira & Paul Pritchard, Univ. of Cambridge Inst. for Sustainability Leadership, Justice in the Transition to a Low Carbon Economy (2016) (unpublished working paper), http://www.cisl.cam.ac.uk/publications/
publication-pdfs/justice-in-the-transition-to-a-low-carbon-economy.pdf [http://perma.cc/
CPY8-VNQT] (“A more explicit consideration of justice issues in the transition to a low carbon economy is increasingly called for by both governmental and civil society actors in national and international fora.”).
The question then becomes: Who determines what additional values are relevant? The sections that follow contend that state politics present a better avenue for this determination than quasi-private, regional electricity markets.

B. State Policies as Reflections of the Social Project of Decarbonization

Although no state has embraced a vision of decarbonization near either extreme described above, state responses to climate change simi­larly evince an understanding of the significant political and value choices bound up in decarbonization policy.

Take, for example, state variations in RPSs, which demonstrate pref­erences for certain resources that are either locally abundant (for example, Maryland’s chicken manure) or particularly desirable, but less economi­cally competitive (for example, rooftop solar carve-outs). 148 See supra section I.B. In both of these instances, states have chosen to promote certain aims beyond “mere decarbonization”—that is, the lowest-cost decarbonization achievable. 149 Indeed, even the choice of a renewables requirement—as opposed to a broader “clean energy” standard—illustrates a preference in this regard. Lincoln Davies catalogues the many “ancillary benefits” an RPS can bring. Davies, Power Forward, supra note 84, at 1357–59. By including chicken manure in its RPS, Maryland provided a potential additional stream of revenue to the state’s many poultry farmers, while diverting nitrogen-rich poultry manure from running off into the Chesapeake Bay—a body of water that has faced significant problems of nitrogen overloading. 150 See Dep’t of Legislative Servs. of Md. Gen. Assembly, Fiscal and Policy Note: S.B. 348, Renewable Energy Portfolio Standard—Tier 1 Renewable Source—Poultry Litter 4–5 (2008), http://mlis.state.md.us/2008rs/fnotes/bil_0008/sb0348.pdf [http://perma.cc/
VRQ8-L9GB].

By including solar and distributed generation carve-outs, states have prioritized controlling both the type and scale of their clean-energy build-out. A policy preference for distributed generation ensures that renewable energy built in a state will not all occur in large-scale, utility- or developer-led projects that consume open space. Instead, some of it will be located on the roofs and in the yards of state residents, providing them additional income streams and creating opportunities for new busi­nesses to emerge in the electricity sphere. 151 See, e.g., Community Energy Solar, http://communityenergysolar.com/about [http://perma.cc/73SW-BEUM] (last visited Feb. 15, 2018) (noting that the company focuses on community solar development). A built-in preference for solar serves a different end: It ensures that all of a state’s renewable energy will not come from the cheapest source—frequently wind—but instead that state policy will work to promote multiple renewable energy technologies. 152 See, e.g., About the Solar Carve-Out Program, Mass. Exec. Office of Energy & Envtl. Affairs, http://www.mass.gov/eea/energy-utilities-clean-tech/renewable-energy/
solar/rps-solar-carve-out/about-the-rps-solar-carve-out-program.html
[http://perma.cc/
SQ6J-56ZD] (last visited Jan. 18, 2018) (articulating multiple goals for Massachusetts’s solar carve-out program, including cultivating a long-term solar market in the state and encouraging build-out of systems of various sizes, including residential, commercial, and utility-scale).

Direct procurement policies for particular resources serve a similar purpose: They signal a commitment to developing a certain local clean-energy industry. Massachusetts politicians celebrated the state’s 2016 legislation mandating offshore wind on this ground, proclaiming, for example: “What we have here, as opposed to an amorphous bill of clean energy generally or greenhouse gases generally, is a specific technology—an offshore wind economy—that we’re hoping to jump start and we have real incentives in place to make that happen.” 153 Elise Harmon, In 2016, Massachusetts Passed a Landmark Renewable Energy Bill—Here’s What You Need to Know, New Eng. Climate Change Rev. Blog (Dec. 19, 2016) (quoting Robert Fitzpatrick, director of government affairs for the Massachusetts Clean Energy Center), http://www.northeastern.edu/climatereview/?p=294 [http://perma.cc/
C4E3-4VKK]; see also Press Release, Governor Charlie Baker, Governor Baker Signs Comprehensive Energy Diversity Legislation (Aug. 8, 2016), http://www.mass.gov/governor/
press-office/press-releases/fy2017/governor-baker-signs-comprehensive-energy-diversity-law.html [http://perma.cc/5D3C-H2P3] (discussing a commitment to “providing resi­dents and businesses with a . . . reliable clean energy future”).

New York tells a similar story about its ZEC program for nuclear energy. The New York Public Service Commission asserts that without support for nuclear, it would be exceedingly difficult for the state to accomplish its RPS goal of 50% renewables by 2030. 154 Memorandum of Law in Support of Defendants’ Motion to Dismiss Complaint Pursuant to Fed. R. Civ. Pro. 12(b)(6) at 3–5, Coal. for Competitive Elec. v. Zibelman, 272 F. Supp. 3d 554 (S.D.N.Y. 2017) (No. 16-CV-8164 (VEC)), 2016 WL 10076867. Although nuclear power does not count towards this 50% goal, “[i]f the nuclear plants were to retire before the renewable build-out occurs, the resulting gap in the state’s power supply would lead to a surge in [greenhouse gas] emis­sions as fossil-fuel-fired generators fill that gap.” 155 Id. Accordingly, the Commission has designed the ZEC as a time-limited measure to assist the state in meeting its long-term decarbonization targets. 156 The ZEC expires, at least under current plans, in 2029. Clean Energy Standard Order, supra note 99, at 156. It also decided to provide nuclear energy a fixed level of support, pegged to predicted wholesale market prices, rather than allow it to receive the fluctuating, often more generous prices awarded to renewables. 157 Whereas nuclear energy receives $17.50 per megawatt hour under the ZEC plan, renewables in 2017 were compensated at the rate of around $21 per megawatt hour. Compare id. at 20, with 2018 Compliance Year, N.Y. State Energy Res. & Dev. Auth. (NYSERDA), http://www.nyserda.ny.gov/All-Programs/Programs/Clean-Energy-Standard/
REC-and-ZEC-Purchasers/2018-Compliance-Year [http://perma.cc/4C2G-NQPN] (last visited Mar. 21, 2018). The price awarded to renewables has fallen to $17 per megawatt hour for 2018, supra 2018 Compliance Year, but is likely to rebound in the com­ing years, as New York rapidly increases the stringency of its utilities’ renewable purchasing obligations. See REC and ZEC Purchasers, N.Y. State Energy Res. & Dev. Auth., http://www.nyserda.ny.gov/All-Programs/Programs/Clean-Energy-Standard/REC-and-ZEC-Purchasers [http://perma.cc/
DXT9-2QYJ] (last visited Mar. 21, 2018) (detailing New York’s increasing “Tier 1 REC” purchase requirements from 2018 through 2021).
Illinois is even more explicitly far-reaching in the aims of its ZEC program: The title of its governing legislation is the “Future Energy Jobs Bill,” and leaders in the state have touted the ZEC program for its job-preserving potential. 158 See Governor Bruce Rauner Signed the Future Energy Jobs Bill, Bruce Rauner, http://www.brucerauner.com/news/governor-bruce-rauner-signed-the-future-energy-jobs-bill/ [http://perma.cc/MZH4-4FYR] (last visited Feb. 15, 2018) (observing that the bill saves “thousands of good-paying jobs”).

Each of these policies reflects decisions by state actors—either the legislature or the commission in charge of electricity—to pursue courses of decarbonization that focus on goals beyond the most efficient removal of carbon. 159 New York made this point most poignantly in its filings for the FERC conference on integrating markets and public policy: “Incorporating a single policy goal into the fed­eral wholesale markets may seemingly help reach that one goal, but may frustrate the mul­tilayered approach carefully designed by the State and reflects a misunderstanding and oversimplification of a State’s multi-faceted policy framework.” Scott A. Weiner, N.Y. State Pub. Serv. Comm’n, Pre-Technical Conference Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 4 (2017) [hereinafter Weiner, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/
20
170426150501-Weiner,%20NY%20State%20DPS.pdf [http://perma.cc/2TC2-2F6U].
They want their decarbonization policies to also create new local industries and jobs, provide new ways for consumers to produce energy close to home, solve contemporaneous environmental challenges, preserve open space and utilize abandoned lots or existing structures, and stabilize energy prices and air emissions during a period of dramatic transition.

C. Is It All Just Rent Seeking?

It is not difficult to conjure up a public-choice-minded skeptic’s swift reaction to my argument: social project? These state policies are all just examples of successful rent seeking, in which certain powerful industries are benefitting to the detriment of the people of the state! 160 “Public choice models . . . treat the legislative process as a microeconomic system in which ‘actual political choices are determined by the efforts of individuals and groups to further their own interests; these efforts have been labeled ‘rent-seeking.’” Daniel A. Farber & Philip P. Frickey, The Jurisprudence of Public Choice, 65 Tex. L. Rev. 873, 878 (1987) (quoting Gary S. Becker, A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence, 98 Q.J. Econ. 371, 371 (1983)) (describing but not endorsing these models). For more on public choice theories of legislation and regulation, see Mancur Olson, The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups 141–48 (1965) (discussing “special interest” theory and business lobbies); Martin Gilens & Benjamin I. Page, Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens, 12 Persp. Pol. 564, 566 (2014) (“A quite different theoretical tradition argues that U.S. policy making is dominated by individuals who have substantial economic resources, i.e., high levels of income or wealth—including, but not limited to, ownership of business firms.”); Mathew D. McCubbins et al., Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control, 3 J.L. Econ. & Org. 243, 243 (1987) (“A central problem of representative democracy is how to ensure that policy decisions are responsive to the interests or preferences of citizens.”); Richard A. Posner, Theories of Economic Regulation, 5 Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. 335, 341–42 (1974) (discussing some versions of the “capture theory”); George J. Stigler, The Theory of Economic Regulation, 2 Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. 3, 3 (1971) (discussing the power of industries to influence and shape regulation for their own benefit). A proponent of the rent-seeking hypothesis might suggest that most of the state pol­icies detailed in this Article are deviations from the most efficient way to decarbonize, which would be to simply put a price on carbon. 161 See infra note 183 and accompanying text. These deviations might be the result of successful lobbying on the part of particular clean-energy industries—including nuclear, wind, and solar—which have secured for themselves premium prices for their particular type of clean energy at the expense of ratepayers, who are largely unor­ganized, politically powerless players in these debates.

It is certainly important not to be naïve about the motivations behind state climate policies. To respond to these concerns, this section makes two brief points. First, this Article’s argument does not turn on a rejec­tion of public choice theory or on proof that harmful rent seeking is absent from state climate policy. Public debate and public churn about the aims and methods of decarbonization are valuable even if they some­times result in certain industries getting a boost. Unjustified rent seeking can be (and is being 162 See infra section III.C (discussing lawsuits against state policies). ) contested through the courts and in the theater of public debate. In contrast, utilizing RTO governance structures and energy markets as the locus for debating, hashing out, and implementing decarbonization policy shunts these debates to much more private, inaccessible quarters—without eliminating the distinct possibility of rent seeking also occurring in those forums. 163 On RTO governance processes, see infra section III.B.

Second, it is not clear that state decarbonization policy preferences can easily be shrugged aside as examples of problematic rent seeking. To be sure, some of these state policies appear to favor certain industries. But in the case of the most dominant state policy, RPS, it is more fledg­ling solar and wind developers who stand to benefit most—at the expense of established fossil fuel companies. That’s hardly a predictable outcome under a public choice explanation of the companies most likely to hold sway with government. The same holds true for numerous other state policies that work against incumbent utility interests. 164 See Elias L. Quinn & Adam L. Reed, Envisioning the Smart Grid: Network Architecture, Information Control, and the Public Policy Balancing Act, 81 U. Colo. L. Rev. 833, 869–79 (2010) (explaining utilities’ mixed motivations when it comes to introducing smart grid technologies); Michael P. Vandenbergh & Jim Rossi, Good for You, Bad for Us: The Financial Disincentive for Net Demand Reduction, 65 Vand. L. Rev. 1527, 1531–34 (2012) (explaining why utilities are so opposed to reducing demand); see also Peter Kind, Energy Infrastructure Advocates, Disruptive Challenges: Financial Implications and Strategic Responses to a Changing Retail Electric Business 17 (2013), http://
www.ourenergypolicy.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/09/disruptivechallenges-1.pdf [http://
perma.cc/6ADJ-TKZJ] (setting forth utility concerns with the popular policy of “net metering” to promote rooftop solar).
The case of ZEC programs for nuclear may seem to better conform to a classic public choice account of a large corporation persuading lawmakers to give it special treatment. Even there, though, the supporters of the policy defy simplistic explanation—the ZEC program divided the environmental community, with many groups coming out in support of it. 165 Clean Energy Standard Order, supra note 99, at 53 (noting “comments among environmental groups are divided”). This divi­sion suggests that many saw ZECs as productively serving decarbonization goals.

Moreover, even accepting that some rent seeking may be at work in these policies, it might not be bad rent seeking. 166 Many scholars have remarked on the indeterminacy of the concept of “rent seek­ing”—one person’s “rent” is another person’s social-welfare gain. Mark Kelman, On Democracy-Bashing: A Skeptical Look at the Theoretical and “Empirical” Practice of the Public Choice Movement, 74 Va. L. Rev. 199, 227 (1988) (“When public choice theorists observe that the political process is an arena of ‘rent-seeking,’ they are being so conceptu­ally ambiguous in their condemnation that they have simply muddied our discourse.”); Daryl J. Levinson, Foreword: Looking for Power in Public Law, 130 Harv. L. Rev. 31, 119 (2016) (describing the difficulty of constructing a persuasive “normative account of how much political power various groups should rightly possess [and] setting a baseline from which to measure disproportionate influence”); see also Farber & Frickey, supra note 160, at 896 (“[A] finding of differential impact often can be effectively challenged. Researchers disa­gree, for example, over whether trucking regulation benefited owners, drivers, or both.”). Scholars have posited several ways in which policy mechanisms that favor certain groups may produce more efficacious or efficient outcomes than neutral policies. Professor Eric Biber has made the case that when it comes to climate change, state policies that build interest-group support may create “polit­ical momentum” that prevents backsliding and allows for a gradual ratch­eting up of the ambition of climate policies. 167 Eric Biber, Cultivating a Green Political Landscape: Lessons for Climate Change Policy from the Defeat of California’s Proposition 23, 66 Vand. L. Rev. 399, 402 (2013); see also Jonas Meckling et al., Winning Coalitions for Climate Policy, 349 Science 1170, 1170 (2015) (“Green industrial policy creates and enhances low-carbon industries, which brings economic constituencies into coalitions for decarbonization, as well as giving feedback that drives progress toward more comprehensive climate policy.”); Matthew Wansley, Virtuous Capture, 67 Admin. L. Rev. 419, 422–23 (2015) (arguing that “rent-seeking is not socially wasteful” when it allows “political actors . . . [to] use interest groups—by altering their power and incentives—to pursue public-interested regulatory goals”). Similarly, Professor Zach Liscow and Quentin Karpilow argue that when government’s goal is to encourage innovation—as it is in the realm of decarbonization—state policies that “specifically encourage cleantech” may be more efficient than technology-neutral policies like a carbon tax. 168 Zachary Liscow & Quentin Karpilow, Innovation Snowballing and Climate Law, 95 Wash. U. L. Rev. 387, 403, 444 (2017) (asserting that “innovation spillovers,” in which cleantech innovation builds on itself, “alone might justify government use of deployment subsidies” which “can help direct innovation flows . . . away from dirtytech and towards cleantech”). As a separate justification, Professors William Boyd and Ann Carlson have made a federalism-based, “laboratories of democracy”–type argument for why we should want states to experiment with different ways to decarbonize. 169 See Boyd & Carlson, supra note 6, at 817; see also N.Y. State Pub. Serv. Comm’n v. N.Y. Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 158 FERC ¶ 61,137 (Feb. 3, 2017), 2017 WL 496267, at *12 (Bay, Comm’r, concurring) (celebrating state laboratories for their ability to “incentivize the development of needed energy infrastructure, the deployment of innovative technologies, or the establishment of Renewable Portfolio Standards”).

These scholars advance pragmatic arguments as to why state policies that favor certain pathways to decarbonization might make political or economic sense. 170 Professor Rossi has recently advanced the argument that state decarbonization policies “can better promote efficiency and social welfare by aligning the features of inter­nal customer subsidies with the same principles that would inform design of a carbon tax.” Rossi, Carbon Taxation, supra note 8, at 279. This suggestion works if indeed the state views efficiency as a good measure of social welfare. But if a state determines that other aims trump efficiency, then it might be perfectly justified in choosing policies that deviate substantially from a carbon tax. This Article’s argument is broader: Any apparent rent seeking in these policies may be justified as a way to fulfill values related to decarbonization that go beyond efficiency. 171 Cf. Mark Sagoff, Economic Theory and Environmental Law, 79 Mich. L. Rev. 1393, 1396–97 (1981) (explaining how many of our laws appropriately reflect preferences for ends other than efficiency); Spence, Naïve Energy Markets, supra note 37, at 1024 (suggesting that Americans are interested in fairness and protection from market failure in addition to efficiency maximization). When states establish climate change policies, they are—at least in part—channeling value judgments about how decarbonization should proceed. 172 The democratic link might appear weaker when agencies—rather than legisla­tures—make decisions about the shape of decarbonization policy. There is, however, a literature suggesting that agencies might be better positioned in some ways to adopt dem­ocratically determined preferences. See Jerry L. Mashaw, Greed, Chaos, and Governance: Using Public Choice to Improve Public Law 37 (1999); Mark Seidenfeld, A Civic Republican Justification for the Administrative State, 105 Harv. L. Rev. 1512, 1515 (1992); David B. Spence & Frank Cross, A Public Choice Case for the Administrative State, 89 Geo. L.J. 97, 101–02 (2000).

Emerging research suggests that the public has distinct preferences and value judgments related to decarbonization. In response to surveys and deliberative polls, individuals have expressed several values beyond pure economic efficiency they consider important in energy systems change, including “not wasting;” environmental protection; stability, reli­ability, and affordability; autonomy and freedom; and social justice and fairness. 173 Butler et al., Public Values, supra note 147, at 667. These diverse values lead people to have strong preferences for certain technologies over others; 174 Professor Dirk Scheer and his coauthors find a strong preference for renewable energy over fossil fuel generation combined with “carbon capture and storage.” Dirk Scheer et al., Public Evaluation of Electricity Technologies and Future Low-Carbon Portfolios in Germany and the USA, 3 Energy, Sustainability & Soc’y, no. 8, 2013, at 1; see also Butler et al., Public Values, supra note 147, at 670 (describing “public visions” as “con­verg[ing] with policy on some of the key areas, specifically reductions in fossil fuels, increases in RETS . . . , and the need for reductions in demand”); Demski et al., supra note 147, at 59–60, 66 (finding a strong public preference, through deliberative work­shops, among U.K. residents for “micro-generation technologies”); Nick Pidgeon & Christina C. Demski, From Nuclear to Renewable: Energy System Transformation and Public Attitudes, 68 Bull. Atomic Sci. 41, 42 (2012) (describing preference for nuclear over wind in one Welsh county). a concern for low-income protections and bill stability over “affordability” as a general metric; 175 See Butler et al., Public Values, supra note 147, at 669 (finding that the group studied was more concerned with “subsidies for low income households and developments to ensure cost stability over and above lowest cost possible”). skepti­cism about market mechanisms over regulatory approaches; 176 Id. at 670. and a desire to “be heard” on energy system preferences. 177 Shelley Welton, Grasping for Energy Democracy, 116 Mich. L. Rev. 581, 585–87 (2018) [hereinafter Welton, Grasping for Energy Democracy] (documenting the growing demands of citizen groups focused on “energy democracy” to be included in the creation of energy regulation); see also Leslie Mabon et al., Deliberative Decarbonisation? Assessing the Potential of an Ethical Governance Framework for Low-Carbon Energy Through the Case of Carbon Dioxide Capture and Storage, 33 Envt. & Plan. C: Gov’t & Pol’y 256, 258–59 (2015) (suggesting that current governance processes for decarboniza­tion suffer from “epistemic injustice” in the ways that “particular technologies come to be conceived as solutions to the problems of climate change”).

Many of these same preferences emerge in state decarbonization policies—for example, in concerns over who is benefited and who is bur­dened by particular policies, in the widespread tendency to favor the pro­motion of renewable energy above nuclear energy, and in many states’ particular emphasis on individuals’ ability to choose their own energy supply. State policies on decarbonization, then, can be seen as attempts to capture the “messy, pluralistic, and pragmatic” goals associated with the social project of decarbonization and to give voice to community judgments regarding the desired shape of our future decarbonized soci­ety. 178 See Kysar, supra note 38, at 3, 15–16 (making the argument that these charac­teristics have always described the diverse goals of environmental policymaking). Responding to and incorporating these preferences helps a state maintain broad citizen support for its decarbonization initiatives. With­out this support, passing the laws necessary to reach “deep decarboniza­tion” levels of carbon mitigation will be all the more difficult.

Of course, there is no guarantee that state policies are accurately chan­neling residents’ preferences in these regards. 179 Cf. Gilens & Page, supra note 160, at 565 (finding that “mass-based interest groups and average citizens have little or no independent influence” on U.S. government policy, but also observing that these policies track their preferences “roughly two-thirds of the time”). Indeed, I have argued elsewhere that energy law should pay more attention to how citizen preferences are generated, understood, and incorporated into decisionmaking around decarbonization. 180 See Welton, Grasping for Energy Democracy, supra note 177, at 586 (identifying three emerging conceptions of what “energy democracy” might entail, including con­sumer choice, local control, and access to process). Nevertheless, one need not have perfect faith in state democracies 181 Nor should one: Several recent articles do excellent work in reminding us why we should not “put state democracy on a pedestal.” See David Schleicher, Federalism and State Democracy, 95 Tex. L. Rev. 763, 767–68 (2017) (arguing state and local elections often “have little to do with anything that ought to matter––like the past performance of state government, or candidates’ positions on issues in front of the state or local govern­ments”); Miriam Seifter, Further from the People? The Puzzle of State Administration, 93 N.Y.U. L. Rev. (forthcoming 2018) (manuscript at 3) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (discussing the role of civil society oversight at the state level and finding that “state agencies are, on the whole, less transparent than their federal counterparts, less closely followed by watchdog groups, and less tracked by the shrinking state-level media”); see also Jim Rossi, The Electric Deregulation Fiasco: Looking to Regulatory Federalism to Promote a Balance Between Markets and the Provision of Public Goods, 100 Mich. L. Rev. 1768, 1782 (2002) (book review) (arguing that state regulatory processes are more amena­ble to capture than federal regulatory processes). in order to accept the central argu­ment of this Article, which is one of comparative institutional compe­tence. 182 Cf. Komesar, supra note 21, at 3–4 (arguing that “institutional choice is an essen­tial part of law and public policy choice” and advocating for a “participation-centered” framework for “doing comparative institutional analysis”). The choices currently on the table for states pursuing decarbon­ization are either (1) maintain robust state public policies as a way to establish the contours of decarbonizing electricity or (2) transfer central responsibility for ensuring decarbonization to regional electricity mar­kets. The next Part describes why regional electricity markets are a trouble­some mechanism for accomplishing the social project of decarbonization.

III. Electricity-Market Redesign to Accomplish the Project of Decarbonization

Almost every academic (myself included) prefers that policies to address climate change include some sort of national carbon tax or cap-and-trade scheme. 183 There is, however, debate regarding whether carbon pricing should be supple­mented with additional policies. See Ann E. Carlson, Designing Effective Climate Policy: Cap-and-Trade and Complementary Policies, 49 Harv. J. on Legis. 207, 207 (2012) (explor­ing issues of complementarity and competition between economy-wide carbon policies and more targeted strategies). My argument here regarding the “social nature” of the project of decarbonization leads me to conclude that supplementary policies are desirable to the extent that a polity wants to control the shape of decarbonization. Putting a price on carbon is theoretically appealing because of its potential breadth, simplicity, and efficiency. 184 See Liscow & Karpilow, supra note 168, at 457–63 (collecting sources in favor of carbon pricing); see also Peter Howard & Derek Sylvan, Inst. for Policy Integrity, Expert Consensus on the Economics of Climate Change 2 (2015), http://policyintegrity.org/
files/publications/ExpertConsensusReport.pdf
[http://perma.cc/DE98-N2RW] (report­ing survey results showing that 75% of expert economists favor a market-based mechanism for carbon); Jerry Taylor, Niskanen Ctr., The Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax 3–10 (2015), http://niskanencenter.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/03/The-Conservative-Case-for-a-Carbon-Tax1.pdf [http://perma.cc/K8LE-Z9Q8] (arguing that the alternative to a carbon tax “is a plethora of command-and-control regulatory interventions,” which already “impose a sort of carbon tax”).
Most states with robust decarbonization policies also support some sort of national carbon-pricing scheme, particularly one that would allow them to pursue additional side policies to address their citizens’ decarbonization prefer­ences. 185 Most states do not, however, favor allowing federal policy to preempt supplemen­tary state policies. See Memorandum from Mary D. Nichols, Cal. Air Res. Bd. et al., to Senators Kerry, Graham, & Lieberman (Mar. 30, 2010) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (arguing that federal climate legislation should “establish a national carbon mar­ket and include national programs, while preserving states’ rights to implement their own climate policies”). Despite its theoretical appeal, however, such a scheme is a politi­cal pipe dream in the near term. 186 See, e.g., Timothy Cama, Trump Brings Big Changes to Climate Policies, The Hill (Feb. 10, 2017), http://thehill.com/policy/energy-environment/318824-trump-brings-big-change-to-climate-policies [http://perma.cc/SV8N-JM7F] (discussing the Trump Administration and Republican Congress’s climate policies, which largely favor limiting regulations and enacting measures to “unwind Obama-era rules on energy”).

In its place, proponents have advanced the idea of addressing decar­bonization within regional electricity markets as a compromise measure. Although covering less of the country and less of the economy than a federal carbon price, including decarbonization aims in electricity markets still holds some advantages over state-by-state efforts. The many parties in favor of using markets to achieve decarbonization goals argue that market incorporation represents the most feasible way, in the cur­rent political climate, to efficiently decarbonize. 187 See infra notes 197–199. At the same time, they suggest, incorporating state climate goals into markets would help con­trol the purported damage that variegated state climate policies do to regional electricity markets. 188 See supra section I.C.

This Part first describes leading proposals for how to achieve state climate goals through RTO markets and the governance processes these proposals would have to go through. It then advances three reasons why the compromise measure of achieving decarbonization through electric­ity markets is a risky substitute for robust, democratically determined action on climate change. In brief, these reasons are that (1) procedur­ally, given RTO governance structures, using these market constructs to achieve climate goals would remove decisions over decarbonization fur­ther from the public view and democratic oversight; (2) substantively, incorporating climate goals into regional electricity markets would homogenize and water down state preferences; and (3) recent Supreme Court precedent creates a risk that once states cede control over decarboni­zation to an RTO, they may give away some ability to adopt supplementary policies to strengthen or shape the trajectory of their decarbon­ization efforts.

A. Proposed Market Reforms to Achieve State Policies

Stakeholders have proposed two predominant reforms to incorpo­rate state climate aims into regional electricity markets. The first is for electricity markets to create their own carbon-pricing systems, analogous to a carbon tax. Thus, for example, certain stakeholders in New England’s RTO have proposed the following scheme:

Under a carbon pricing system, each electricity producer would pay an emissions fee in direct proportion to the amount of car­bon (in tons) its generation facilities emit. The carbon emis­sions price (that is, the fee per ton emitted) could be fixed, be a set price schedule that increases over time, or be dynamically adjusted based on aggregate performance over time to satisfy specific carbon reduction objectives. 189 ISO New England, NEPOOL 2016 IMAPP Proposals: Observations, Issues, and Next Steps 2 (2017) [hereinafter ISO-NE Proposal], http://www.iso-ne.com/static-assets/
documents/2017/03/iso-ne_jan_2017_imapp_memo_vtransmit2.pdf [http://perma.cc/
2354-QND3]. The ways in which this scheme would interact with the current carbon-pricing regime in the New England region are discussed in section IV.B.

PJM—the mid-Atlantic RTO—has proposed a similar scheme, sug­gesting a carbon-pricing system might also be pursued by a subset of the region interested in a carbon price, should the entire region prove unable to reach agreement. 190 PJM, Advancing Zero Emissions Objectives Through PJM’s Energy Markets: A Review of Carbon-Pricing Frameworks 1 (2017) [hereinafter PJM, Advancing Zero Emissions Objectives], http://pjm.com/~/media/library/reports-notices/special-reports/20170502-
advancing-zero-emission-objectives-through-pjms-energy-markets.ashx [http://perma.cc/
J9B9-4N5X].
And New York’s RTO has also come out in favor of a car­bon-pricing scheme in that single-state market. 191 See Bradley C. Jones, President & CEO, N.Y. Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc. (NYISO), Pre-Technical Conference Comments at the FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 4 (2017), http://www.ferc.gov/
CalendarFiles/20170426150524-Jones,%20NYISO.pdf [http://perma.cc/C3W3-BV88].
New York’s proposal focuses on using the (now-defunct, federal 192 See supra note 101. ) “social cost of carbon” to create a “carbon adder” for each generator based on its car­bon emis­sions. 193 Justin Gundlach & Romany Webb, Sabin Ctr. for Climate Change Law, Columbia Law Sch., Carbon Pricing in New York ISO Markets: Federal and State Issues 31 (2017), http://columbiaclimatelaw.com/files/2017/02/Gundlach-Webb-2017-02-Carbon-Pricing-in-NYISO-Markets.pdf [http://perma.cc/P79H-2NQB]. “This fee would be added to the prices generators bid into the wholesale electricity market and those adjusted prices used by NYISO to determine the dispatch order.” 194 Id. at iii–iv; see also Samuel A. Newell et al., The Brattle Grp., Pricing Carbon into NYISO’s Wholesale Energy Market to Support New York’s Decarbonization Goals, at v–vii (2017), http://www.nyiso.com/public/webdocs/markets_operations/documents/Studies_
and_Reports/Studies/Market_Studies/Pricing_Carbon_into_NYISOs_Wholesale_Energy_Market.pdf [http://perma.cc/8WRM-EJPU].

A separate set of proposals focuses on using RTOs to run central­ized, market-based procurement processes specifically for clean energy. Thus, for example, an RTO might create a “Forward Clean Energy Market,” in which the market operator would solicit contracts for future commitments of low- or no-carbon resources in an annual auction. 195 See ISO-NE Proposal, supra note 189, at 4–5. This model would, in essence, amalgamate the various state RPSs in a region and attempt to satisfy them all at the same time and at the lowest cost. Such a scheme would also guarantee renewables a certain amount of revenue into the future, helping to create the certainty necessary to obtain project financing. 196 Id.

Proponents of these reforms include many clean-energy as well as fossil-fuel generators, 197 See, e.g., Aleksandar Mitreski, Senior Dir., Regulatory Affairs, Brookfield Renewable, Panel 2: Stakeholder’s Perspective in ISO-NE (Apr. 26, 2017), http://
www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170426150309-Mitreski,%20Brookfield%20Renewable.pdf
[http://perma.cc/TS2G-98KR]; John E. Shelk, President & CEO, Elec. Power Supply Ass’n, Opening Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 2 (May 1, 2017) [hereinafter EPSA, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170426150649-Shelk,%20EPSA.pdf [http://perma.cc/8C3L-BFTK] (“States have an important role to play given that the FPA reserves retail jurisdiction to States . . . . However, it is critical that fed­eral and state authori­ties be exercised within the law and in concert to achieve federal and state policy objec­tives consistent with well-functioning wholesale power markets.”); NRG Energy, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 120, at 1–2 (“The uniform American experience is that competition drives down prices, increases quality of service, and encour­ages technical innovation.”).
well-regarded market analysts, 198 See, e.g., Samuel A. Newell, Principal, Brattle Grp., Comments at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 2 (Apr. 25, 2017) [hereinafter Brattle Group, FERC Technical Conference], http://www.ferc.gov/
CalendarFiles/20170426151703-Newell,%20The%20Brattle%20Group.pdf [http://perma.cc/
X6VM-3XCT
] (“Harnessing competition will be critical for spurring innovation and guiding technology choices to help meet environmental and reliability objectives cost effectively. The centralized whole­sale markets can best orchestrate this kind of competition if they are enhanced to incorpo­rate the states’ decarbonization objectives.”).
and several states and environmental groups. 199 See Erwin, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 113, at 5 (“FERC should investigate placing value on the avoided externalized costs of non-emitting generation resources.”); Andrew G. Place, Vice Chairman, Penn. Pub. Util. Comm’n, Pre-Technical Conference Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 3–4 (Apr. 25, 2017), http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/
20170426150811-Place,%20Pennsylvania%20PUC.pdf [http://perma.cc/B6LM-WC45] (laud­ing the potential efficiencies of these solutions); Angela M. O’Connor, Chairman, Mass. Dep’t of Pub. Util., Pre-Technical Conference Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 4 (Apr. 2017), http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170426150007-O’Connor,%20Massachuetts%20DPU.pdf [http://perma.cc/JR4B-4FTR] (“Massachusetts . . . remains firmly committed to finding market-based solutions that can not only accommodate our currently effective statutory requirements in the short-term, but that can also provide market-based frameworks for accomplishing the Commonwealth’s goals through the competitive markets on a long-term basis.”). But not all states and environmental groups are on board—many have come out at least against certain types of market integration. See, e.g., Memorandum from New England States Comm. on Elec. to New England Power Pool, supra note 16, at 1 (“NESCOE confirms that it does not support an additional carbon pricing-style mechanism in furtherance of state laws . . . .” (footnote omitted)); Brien J. Sheahan, Chairman, Ill. Commerce Comm’n, Pre-Technical Conference Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 3 (2017), http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/
20170426150841-Sheahan,%20Illinois%20Commerce%20Commission.pdf [http://perma.cc/
XFV8-BAUF] (“Illinois supports regional market design modifications that either complement or enhance state policy initiatives.”); Robert B. Stoddard, Conservation Law Found., Prefiled Comments at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 3 (Apr. 2017), http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/
20170426151751-Stoddard,%20Conservation%20Law%20Foundation.pdf [http://perma.cc/
HJ8Z-2T4H] [hereinafter Conservation Law Found., FERC Technical Conference] (supporting a “carbon adder” but explaining that its “practical drawbacks” led the organization to “develop a supplementary financial instrument to address these deficiencies”). Note that NESCOE does support further exploration of a Forward Clean Energy Market. Memorandum from New England States Comm. on Elec. To New England Power Pool, supra, at 4.
There is an obvious reason for this broad-based support: Pricing carbon into electricity markets should help to achieve electricity-sector carbon-emissions reductions more efficiently, since a market price drives innovation and doesn’t predetermine win­ners. 200 See Liscow & Karpilow, supra note 168, at 389–97 (collecting sources making this argument); Jonas J. Monast et al., On Morals, Markets, and Climate Change: Exploring Pope Francis’ Challenge, 80 Law & Contemp. Probs., no. 1, 2017, at 139 (“Incorporating externalities into the cost of production has the virtue of ‘getting the price right’ and moves the market toward the economically efficient outcome from a utilitarian social wel­fare maximization perspective, in which the price paid for a good reflects the full marginal cost of its production.”); Brattle Group, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 198, at 3 (“The most market-oriented approach to implementing a decarbonization policy is to price carbon emissions.”). Similarly, having a market scheme procure all of a region’s renew­able-energy demand would be a more efficient way to meet state RPSs than having each state’s utilities go it alone. 201 See Brattle Group, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 198, at 4 (“[C]lean energy markets would maximize competition and innovation by admitting new and exist­ing resources of all clean technologies (although they still would not provide as broad a price signal as carbon prices).”); see also ISO-NE Proposal, supra note 189, at 4. As a substantive matter, then, the argument for subsuming state climate policies into markets is relatively straightforward: It offers a more efficient way to accomplish state public policy aims while keeping electricity prices as “just and reasonable” as possible. Relatedly, it avoids the need to constantly guard against potential market distortions caused by state public policies, thus maintaining predictable, well-functioning competitive markets. 202 See, e.g., EPSA, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 197, at 2 (arguing that FERC should incorporate decarbonization policies into markets as the strategy most “con­sistent with investing private at-risk capital based on market price signals”).

Despite widespread support, these proposals are not without challenges. One of these is legal—it is not clear that federally overseen electricity markets have the mandate to include environmental considera­­tions within their dispatch models. As noted in the introduction, many excellent legal minds are engaged in this analysis. 203 See supra note 35. A second challenge is less strictly legal in nature, although it implicates jurisdictional fric­tions. It is relatively clear what states might gain from integrating climate policies into regional electricity markets. But no action is without tradeoffs. What, then, do they stand to lose? The remainder of this Part tackles this question.

B. How a Stakeholder Proposal Becomes a Tariff Provision: The Intricacies of RTO Governance

To enact a regional decarbonization mechanism, a proposal would first have to clear complex RTO and FERC governance processes. RTOs are “Frankenstein like” 204 John P. Hughes, President & CEO, Elec. Consumers Res. Council (ELCON), Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 325 (May 2, 2017), http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/
20170530122053-Transcript,%20May%202,%202017.pdf [http://perma.cc/R7MN-B7EZ].
hybridized creatures, singular in their structure. 205 Christina Simeone, Kleinman Ctr. for Energy Pol’y, PJM Governance: Can Reforms Improve Outcomes? 22 (2017) (“As organizations, RTO’s are unique in structure, authority, and function.”). To be sure, one might include RTOs in the larger category of “quasi-governmental institutions,” but to group them there does little to illuminate their particular pathologies, which are of interest here. Cf. Osofsky & Wiseman, supra note 12, at 7 (describing the “inadequate jurisdictional authority, related concerns of overlapping or fragmented authority, and heavy involvement of private actors in energy governance” of RTOs). These organizations operate as not-for-profit corporations, governed by a board of directors and overseen by FERC. 206 See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., By-Laws § 2.1 (effective Dec. 1, 2009), http://
www.pjm.com/~/media/documents/corp-docs/by-laws.ashx [http://perma.cc/R8LZ-DQZC] (establishing a PJM Board elected by PJM members to “manage the business and affairs of the Company”); see also California ISO (CAISO), Docket No. 16-RGO-01, Principles for Governance of a Regional ISO 9 (Oct. 7, 2016) (“PJM, MISO, and ISO-NE all have boards with nine voting members, while SPP has seven voting members.”). Selection processes for the membership of RTO boards have been a matter of some controversy, but such con­troversy exceeds the scope of this Article. See Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 563–67 (reviewing issues that arise in selecting and terminating RTO boards).
Functionally, RTOs manage the day-to-day transfer of electricity across utility transmis­sion lines, as well as coordinate electricity markets. 207 See Regional Transmission Organizations, 65 Fed. Reg. 810, 813–15 (Dec. 20, 1999) (codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35). They exist only in those areas in which utilities have voluntarily ceded operational control of their transmission assets after obtaining the approval of their home states to do so. 208 See id. at 831 (describing the voluntary approach to RTO formation); see also Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 548 (explaining that RTOs are “between government and business”); Daniel Greenfield & John Kwoka, The Cost Structure of Regional Transmission Organizations, 32 Energy J. 159, 163 (2011) (“RTOs are unusual economic institutions. They are not-for-profit corporations that assume control and man­agement of the bulk power transport systems of their member utilities, while the latter continue to own all of those assets.”). Tariffs, by-laws, and operating agreements dictate the terms of RTO operations and governance, and the RTO board must file proposed changes in these documents with FERC for its approval. 209 See 16 U.S.C. § 824d(c)–(d) (2012); see also N.J. Bd. of Pub. Utils. v. FERC, 744 F.3d 74, 83 (3d Cir. 2014) (explaining that “tariff” is “the term of art used to refer to the ‘classifications, practices, and regulations’ a public utility uses to establish electricity rates”); Simeone, supra note 205, at 9 (detailing PJM’s governing documents). In deter­mining whether to approve an RTO’s proposed changes, FERC eval­uates whether they will further “just and reasonable” rates and avoid “unduly discriminatory or preferential” practices, after hearing from interested parties through a notice-and-comment procedure. 210 16 U.S.C. § 824e; see also Peskoe, supra note 35, at 10 (describing how FERC evaluates regional proposals).

Before a board can make such a request to FERC, any proposal must go through internal RTO-governance processes. 211 Note that the description that follows of RTO governance is necessarily a broad sketch, since each region “has its own power and governance structure and each relies on its own particular language and terminology.” Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 561. This Article attempts to capture their substantial similarities. See E4The Future, Inc., Regional Energy Markets: Do Inconsistent Governance Structures Impede U.S. Market Success? 3 (2016) (surveying RTO governance and finding “nearly all” of them follow a process like the one detailed here). RTO boards solicit the opinions and expertise of stakeholders principally through topic-specific committees. 212 See Benjamin A. Stafford & Elizabeth J. Wilson, Winds of Change in Energy Systems: Policy Implementation, Technology Deployment, and Regional Transmission Organizations, 21 Energy Res. & Soc. Sci. 222, 230 (2016) (describing MISO’s engagement with stakeholders). These committees ostensibly allow all stakeholders—persons with an interest in the market rules—to have their views consid­ered. 213 Id. at 224 (“RTO stakeholders represent different interests, including owners of transmission assets, generation assets, power marketers, and environmental advocates as well as industrial energy load, energy market traders, state policy makers, and others.”). But only “members” receive voting privileges. 214 See E4The Future, Inc., supra note 211, at 3 (surveying RTO operating proce­dures and finding that “[w]hile many allow the public to participate in RTO/ISO business activities, most restrict who can fully participate in the stakeholder process by establishing paid membership requirements and allowing voting by members only”). Members are predominantly transmission-owning utilities, generators, and other energy-market participants with financial stakes in market outcomes. 215 See Seth Blumsack et al., Can Capacity Markets Be Designed by Democracy?, Proc. of the 50th Haw. Int’l Conf. on Sys. Sci. 3075, 3076 (2017) (breaking down PJM’s voting members into categories); About 60% of the U.S. Electric Power Supply Is Managed by RTOs, U.S. Energy Info. Admin.: Today in Energy (Apr. 4, 2011), http://www.eia.gov/
todayinenergy/detail.php?id=790 [http://perma.cc/3WEG-MNS4] (explaining the types of members that RTOs have).

Membership rules vary by RTO, but generally becoming a member requires establishing an interest in the operations of the market and pay­ing annual membership dues. 216 See, e.g., 4 Southwest Power Pool, Inc., Bylaws § 2.1 (effective Nov. 10, 2014), http://
www.spp.org/documents/13272/current%20bylaws%20and%20membership%20agreement%20tariff.pdf [http://perma.cc/J9U5-XP4C] (“Qualifications: Membership in SPP is voluntary and is open to any . . . entity willing to meet the membership requirements, including execution of the Membership Agreement.”). Some regions will waive dues for good cause. See, e.g., id. § 8.2 (effective Aug. 5, 2018).
Members are grouped by their interest in the markets, with weighted votes established by group. 217 See Dylan Reed & Arvin Ganesan, How Grid Governance Stands in the Way of Advanced Energy Progress, Advanced Energy Econ.: Advanced Energy Perspectives (Sept. 8, 2016), http://blog.aee.net/how-grid-governance-stands-in-the-way-of-advanced-energy-progress [http://perma.cc/RN5F-NGUG]. Typically, a proposal for reform must obtain a super-majority vote by the members of a committee before it is recommended for the RTO board’s consideration. 218 E4The Future, Inc., supra note 211, at 11 (“The voting thresholds in each stake­holder process require super-majorities in almost every situation.”). PJM, for example, requires that pending motions be approved “by a 75 percent sector-weighted vote of the members present at the committee meeting, where each sector gets a 20 percent share of the vote.” Id. at 6.

RTOs also have structures in place for states to provide input into regional electricity-market governance. Most notably, this influence occurs via “regional state committees” comprised of state representatives (typically utility commissioners) from the states within the RTO’s terri­tory. 219 See Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 588–91 (describing these entities). For examples of regional state committees, see, e.g., Southwest Power Pool, Inc., supra note 216, § 7.2; Independent State Agencies Committee, PJM, http://www.pjm.com/
committees-and-groups/isac.aspx
[http://perma.cc/3J9K-S2PT] (last visited Jan. 19, 2018); New England States Committee on Electricity, http://nescoe.com [http://perma.cc/NSU6-B9N9] (last visited Jan. 19, 2018).
These committees supply feedback to RTO boards of directors on proposed tariff changes, which the boards take into account in deciding whether to recommend any changes to FERC. Such committees do not, however, have any formalized role in the RTO process—a source of con­sternation for some, given how important RTO governance is for state policy outcomes. 220 See Simeone, supra note 205, at 41 (recommending a more formal role for states in RTO governance); Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 588–91 (describing states’ lack of formal influence at RTOs).

Despite these channels of input and influence, RTO boards remain “independent.” 221 See Wholesale Competition in Regions with Organized Electric Markets, 73 Fed. Reg. 64,099, 64,157 (Oct. 17, 2008) (codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35) (discussing the challenge of “balanc[ing] customers’ and other stakeholders’ need for effective access to the boards of RTOs and ISOs, with the need for the independent management of each RTO and ISO”); Stafford & Wilson, supra note 212, at 231 (“All stakeholder voting in MISO is con­sidered ‘advisory’ in nature and MISO is not required [sic] follow stakeholder votes.”). Thus, a board need not formally follow either members’ majority preferences or state wishes. When it submits its final deci­sions to FERC, however, an RTO board frequently explains major devi­ations from members’ recommendations. 222 See, e.g., E4The Future, Inc., supra note 211, at 4 (noting that when the New England RTO provides a proposal to FERC without unanimous stakeholder support, it must “explain in its filing why its proposal is superior”). In practice, then, it is substantially easier for a board to establish that a proposed change is “just and reasonable” if a substantial proportion of its members—and its members’ states—so agree. 223 See supra note 210 and accompanying text (discussing the standard by which FERC evaluates an RTO’s proposed changes). Members, states, or other stakeholders that continue to disagree with an RTO proposal can protest the changes dur­ing FERC’s vetting process or ultimately through a lawsuit. 224 See 16 U.S.C. § 825l(b) (2012). These pro­tests can also be backed up by the more drastic measure of deciding to leave the RTO (in the case of member utilities) 225 See Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 570 (arguing that members’ ability to “vote with [their] feet” threatens RTO independence, as RTOs “desire to retain partici­pants and geographic spread”). or requiring their utili­ties to leave the RTO (in the case of states).

Any decision by an RTO to incorporate decarbonization objectives into market operations would occur through the process outlined above: An RTO board would determine—by a requisite margin of votes—that such changes would help to ensure “just and reasonable rates” and would file a petition with FERC to have such changes approved. FERC would then have the ultimate decision on whether including decar­bonization in RTO market rules would in fact be “just and reasonable.” 226 See 16 U.S.C. § 824d. The remainder of this Part discusses the pathologies that might emerge from using this decisionmaking structure to achieve decar­bonization aims.

C. Resulting Challenges for RTO Control of Decarbonization

Several characteristics of RTOs make them imperfect sites for deci­sions on the shape of decarbonization policies. This section details three particular flaws that should give states pause in ceding control over decarbonization policy to their RTOs: (1) RTO governance presents a diminished space for deliberative, democratic decisionmaking, as com­pared to state politics; (2) RTO-governance structures create a tendency for policies to become homogenized and watered down when adopted at the regional level; and (3) the jurisdictional frictions created by Hughes pose a risk that states may diminish their own tools for controlling decar­bonization if they cede the same functions to their RTOs.

1. A Loss of Public Procedure. — The first challenge of RTO control over decarbonization policies has to do with RTOs’ governance structure, and in particular, the relative sway of various stakeholders and members within RTO governance. Many suspect that stakeholders with assets man­aged by the RTO—that is, transmission owners—have outsized influence, given that they can wield the threat of leaving the RTO should they be dissatisfied with a change in the governing rules. 227 See, e.g., American Municipal Power, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 112, at 2 (suggesting the “rules churn” at PJM provides “a cloak for ‘gaming’ behavior”); see also, e.g., Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 561–62 (noting stakeholder worries that RTOs are not as independent as they should be); Kavulla, supra note 56 (suggesting that “usually . . . moneyed ‘stakeholders’ get their way”); Kenneth Rose, Trouble in Market Paradise: Development of the Regional Transmission Operator, 50 J. Econ. Issues 535, 536 (2016) (noting RTOs’ stakeholders include “market participants” with “strong economic interest[s] in RTO rules and procedures”). Similarly, although “membership” is not limited to these asset holders, weighted voting by membership sector can stack the deck against public interest organiza­tions or those without a strong foothold in the industry. 228 See Blumsack et al., supra note 215, at 3083 (“[T]here may be limits to the degree to which organizations like RTOs can create mechanisms for heterogeneous stake­holders with opposing interests to develop passable market rules and protocols.”).

Moreover, even if the stakeholder-committee processes were viewed as fair, participation in them would still be challenging. In a recent study that interviewed numerous participants in RTO governance, the tenor of many responses was along the following lines: To participate successfully, “you have to be a combination of an economist and a math wizard.” 229 Stafford & Wilson, supra note 212, at 230; see also id. (quoting a respondent des­cribing these processes as “a world of acronyms” in which it is easy to get lost). Others observed that the sheer quantity of stakeholder meetings at RTOs makes it impossible for smaller, less resourced organizations to participate. 230 Id. at 231 (quoting a respondent to highlight the multitude of RTO stakeholder meetings which often occur at overlapping times).

These challenges point to the first key risk of shunting decarboniza­tion policy into RTOs: They offer considerably less transparent, only quasi-public frameworks in which to make these critically important deci­sions. Although RTO-governance processes nominally give boards inde­pendent decisionmaking power (a structure that itself already lessens public accountability), their membership rules and the weight that FERC gives to stakeholder opinions—both as a matter of law and practice—dampen this independence. 231 See Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 562, 570–71 (noting RTOs’ need to “maintain relationships with . . . stakeholders”). Thus, if RTOs take over decarbonization policymaking, it will not be elected public officials or their appointed bureaucrats, but private companies, who will hold much of the power to determine the shape of these efforts.

Having expressed these concerns about stakeholder governance, it is important to acknowledge some limits on the extent to which private companies would shape RTO-led decarbonization efforts, particularly on the front end. No RTO is likely to proceed with decarbonization efforts without support from participating states, at least in the current legal and political climate. 232 In contrast, if significant national climate change policy reemerged, one could imagine an RTO basing its authority to integrate decarbonization goals on this legal requirement, rather than on state legal requirements. States hold this sway because of another feature of RTOs: their explicit disengagement from creating new “policy.” 233 Stafford & Wilson, supra note 212, at 229 (suggesting state-level policy dictates RTO policy). RTO representatives maintain: “We are a taker of policy not a maker of policy. . . . We don’t create policy. We attempt to interpret policy as handed to us.” 234 Id. Because RTOs eschew any role in determining what the “public interest” is, states retain what Professor Christina Simeone has described as “an incredible amount of power and influence” in shaping the interac­tion of public policies and markets. 235 Simeone, supra note 205, at 27.

RTOs disclaim this policymaking function for both political and legal reasons. Politically, it would be substantially harder to convince states to let their utilities join or remain in RTOs if membership meant ceding state policymaking authority to this quasi-private entity. As a legal matter, imagine if an RTO were to include any sort of decarbonization requirement—such as a carbon price—that caused a state’s utilities to pay extra for electricity. For states in which state decarbonization policy supported this change, a “just and reasonable” finding would be under­standable—as noted above, pricing carbon in the market would likely help the state accomplish its aims at the lowest price possible. In contrast, for any state that did not have a policy in place that supported this extra payment, a carbon price might well be “unjust and unreasonable” because it would force the residents of the state to pay more for reasons unsupported by any state or federal policy. 236 See Robert R. Scott, Comm’r, N.H. Pub. Util. Comm’n, Pre-Technical Conference Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 2 (Apr. 25, 2017), http://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/
2017042
6150034-Scott,%20%20NHPUC.pdf [http://perma.cc/T5KY-CHX5] (“[S]tates like New Hampshire that have no legal man­date to reduce carbon emissions beyond RGGI are insistent that they pay none of the costs of implementing other states’ policies.”); see also Peskoe, supra note 35, at 34 & n.217 (explaining that to avoid this legal risk, “an RTO carbon adder should be designed to achieve compliance with public policies and not to mitigate environmental harms”).
Accordingly, any state that did not believe its underlying decarbonization policies justified its utili­ties’ increased costs for wholesale power would have a strong legal claim to advance in front of FERC and the federal judiciary.

There is, in sum, a byzantine set of dynamics facing RTO efforts to integrate state decarbonization aims. RTOs would be unlikely to request such changes in their tariffs unless both stakeholder committees—via super-majority vote—and all states in a region endorsed the request. FERC, similarly, would be unlikely to approve the request if any state felt it unfairly required its customers to pay for more decarbonization than state law mandated. Not only would all of these negotiations occur deeper in the shadows than does state climate change policymaking, but this de facto near-consensus procedural requirement would also likely have troubling substantive impacts, discussed in the following section.

2. Homogenization and the Watering Down of Preferences. — The second challenge with using RTOs to achieve state decarbonization aims is that their structure and legal mandate leaves them with a diminished set of policy tools as compared to states. Accordingly, the use of these markets to achieve state goals would likely entail both homogenization and water­ing down of state preferences.

The more drastic homogenizing force would come from imposition of a carbon price, which would require substantial regional agreement across a range of topics. The entire theory behind a carbon-pricing scheme is that it eliminates aims beyond the cheapest decarbonization achievable. 237 Peskoe, supra note 35, at 34 (suggesting the “social cost of carbon” is not cur­rently reflected in FERC rates). Away would go state preferences for particular types of clean energy, particular locations or scales, or broad-based inclusion or redistribution as a part of decarbonization policy (except to the extent that states continued to pursue these goals through separate, state-specific side policies). 238 See Spence, Naïve Energy Markets, supra note 37, at 988–92, 1001 (describing how energy markets reduce all decisionmaking to economic optimality, ignoring questions of redistribution or values other than efficiency). Whether states could pursue their desired suite of side policies would depend on how circuit courts interpret and apply Hughes–—a topic taken up infra section IV.B.

Moreover, states would also have to homogenize their timing and targets for decarbonization. In order for a carbon price to work, there would likely have to be a single price throughout a region. 239 See PJM, Advancing Zero Emissions Objectives, supra note 190, at 1 (“To avoid significant complexity . . . a single carbon price is required across the carbon price sub-region.”). Brattle Group suggests a multistate region could possibly administer multiple carbon prices, although it admits that such an idea is “complicated” and “needs to be developed further.” See Brattle Group, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 198, at 4. Setting this price would be challenging, given the divergent state decarbonization targets that exist in multistate regions. 240 See Conservation Law Found., FERC Technical Conference, supra note 199, at 1–2 (discussing the complexity of “integrating state policy preferences into RTO Markets”); see also Brian Forshaw, Conn. Mun. Elec. Energy Coop., Written Comments for FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 4 (May 1, 2017) [hereinafter CMEEC, FERC Technical Conference], http://
www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170426150137-Forshaw,%20Energy%20Market%20Advisors.pdf [http://perma.cc/RP35-N3Y9].
To reach region-wide agreement on a price, states with higher targets would either have to accept a price that would not fully satisfy their decarbonization goals, or find a way to refund revenues from the regional carbon-pricing scheme to those neighbor-states that otherwise feel that they would be “overpaying” (a politically contentious work-around, to be sure). 241 See PJM, Advancing Zero Emissions Objectives, supra note 190, at 1–2 (explain­ing the need for states to agree on participation and on a price). This dynamic would create a pull toward a “lowest-common-denominator” level of carbon pricing—which would be bad both for states keen on rapid decarboniza­tion and for free-riding states that want to see their neighbors carry more of the burden of achieving decarbonization. 242 Dworkin & Goldwasser, supra note 51, at 564 (explaining that the structure of RTO governance means that “[t]he need for consensus may result in the least common denominator option winning out”).

A less drastic homogenization of state climate policies might occur in the case of a Forward Clean Energy Market. In this model, states could control their overall level of desired renewable procurement and pass this information on to the market operator. 243 In this way, the Clean Energy Market is not intended “to eliminate or replace state renewable portfolio standards, but . . . is a complimentary system for market procure­ment of the RECs needed to meet the RPS.” Renew Northeast & Nextera Energy, Presentation at NEPOOL IMAPP Meeting: A New IMAPP Proposal 13 (Jan. 25, 2017) (on file with the Columbia Law Review). But such a scheme would still require, at a minimum, agreement on qualifying resources. To be sure, the scheme could be designed to allow states to make requests for certain types, as well as amounts, of renewable power. 244 See id. at 6. The more the market was segmented by resource type, however, the less benefit it would provide in the form of an interstate, least-cost auction. 245 See id. Accord­ingly, a Forward Clean Energy Market would also create pressure to homogenize resource preferences in order to reap the benefits of creat­ing a regional auction. 246 Professor Felix Mormann confirms this argument by making a similar point with respect to the idea of pursuing a federal RPS, arguing that “[g]eographic gains from a federal policy approach would likely come at the expense of a federal RPS’s aspirational aggressiveness,” because a “federally palatable RPS regime . . . would likely aim lower aspi­rationally and, ultimately, have a shallower impact.” Mormann, supra note 36, at 1643.

The homogenizing forces described here present two distinct lines of concern. The first springs from theories of democratic experimentalism. 247 See Michael C. Dorf & Charles F. Sabel, A Constitution of Democratic Experimentalism, 98 Colum. L. Rev. 267, 288 (1998) (arguing for greater use of “demo­cratic experimentalism,” in which localities experiment in government service provision and central regulators facilitate learning from one another’s experimentation). Because decarbonization is in the early stages of what looks to be a long, expensive, transformative slog, perhaps it is best at this stage to allow multiple models to flourish, instead of subsuming state policies into regional markets. Former FERC Chair Norman Bay adopted this position in a concurrence authored right before his resignation, in which he celebrated state decarbonization policies for their experimental character. 248 See N.Y. State Pub. Serv. Comm’n v. N.Y. Indep. Sys. Operator, Inc., 158 FERC ¶ 61,137 (Feb. 3, 2017), 2017 WL 496267, at *12 (Bay, Comm’r, concurring) (“In our consti­tutional order, states are rightly celebrated for being laboratories for experimentation. Among other things, those laboratories may incentivize the development of needed energy infrastructure, the deployment of innovative technologies, or the establishment of Renewable Portfolio Standards.” (footnote omitted)). And Professors Ann Carlson and William Boyd have made a thoughtful case regarding the national decarbonization benefits that such state experiments can produce. 249 See Boyd & Carlson, supra note 6, at 815 (explaining how state diversity in electricity governance has led to “interesting examples of policy innovation”).

This classic “laboratories of democracy” line of argument is compel­ling, but it captures only part of the challenge that states face as they con­sider regionalizing their decarbonization efforts through RTOs. In this context, the choice is not simply between the state, regional, or federal scale as the locus of policymaking. Instead, choosing between the state and regional scale also implicates a fundamental choice between electric­ity markets or regulation as the fundamental driver of decarbonization. States that turn RPSs or carbon pricing over to RTOs must be willing to allow RTO governance to dictate the terms of these policies going for­ward. To relinquish control to a regional electricity market is thus to authorize a diminishment in the suite of tools and scope of control avail­able to publicly manage decarbonization.

3. The Risk of Aggrandizing Market Control. — There is an obvious objection to the argument made in the previous subsection: Why assume that if states were to give regional markets some control over achieving climate change goals, they could not continue to shape decarbonization’s trajectory through complementary side policies if necessary? This argu­ment relates to an argument economists often make about the risks of mixing policy aims: Why not let markets take care of decarbonization as cheaply as possible and then let states craft separate policies to accomplish their additional aims? Wouldn’t this be better than letting states design these inefficient, multifaceted policies that attempt to mash together the goals of decarbonization with social justice and economic growth? 250 See Eric A. Posner & David Weisbach, Climate Change Justice 169–88 (2010) (discussing the “ethical obligations of wealthy nations” in climate change policies); cf. Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell, Should Legal Rules Favor the Poor? Clarifying the Role of Legal Rules and the Income Tax in Redistributing Income, 29 J. Legal Stud. 821, 822–26 (2000) (advocating for an income-tax system, rather than legal rules, as a means of help­ing the poor).

The response to this argument again revolves around the patholo­gies of electricity markets, and in particular, the way these markets oper­ate under shared state and federal jurisdiction. 251 I do not mean to argue that jurisdictional friction presents the only reason that states might prefer to create policies jointly aimed at decarbonization and other social goals. Others have written general rebuttals to the argument that redistributional aims should be separated from other policy goals. See, e.g., Daniel A. Farber, Climate Justice, 110 Mich. L. Rev. 985, 989 (2012) (reviewing Posner & Weisbach, supra note 250) (“To say that we should not engage in redistribution unless we can implement the ideal form of redistribution is really to say that we should not engage in redistribution at all.”); Lee Anne Fennell & Richard H. McAdams, Fairness in Law and Economics: Introduction 5 (Univ. of Chi. Pub. Law & Legal Theory, Working Paper No. 489, 2014) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (arguing the high political costs of tax redistribution may make it cheaper to redistribute outside the tax scheme). The jurisdictional churn in electricity law presents particular reason to eschew using these markets to decarbonize. In brief, the challenge is this: Once a state cedes policy objectives to its regional electricity mar­ket, the state may suffer limits on its ability to craft supplementary poli­cies or to reclaim the objectives if it does not like the results the market produces.

This argument no doubt appears strange at first blush. Why should a state lose its ability to reclaim control over public-policy objectives, if it only voluntarily gives the market control over these objectives in the first place? The complicating factor is a recent line of Supreme Court juris­prudence interpreting the state–federal boundary in electricity law, which updates the longstanding principle that “[s]tates may not regulate in areas where FERC has properly exercised its jurisdiction to determine just and reasonable wholesale rates.” 252 Miss. Power & Light Co. v. Mississippi ex rel. Moore, 487 U.S. 354, 374 (1988).

Of particular relevance is the Supreme Court’s 2016 decision in Hughes v. Talen Energy Marketing, LLC, which considered a subsidy scheme devised by Maryland to incentivize power plants to build in the state. 253 136 S. Ct. 1288, 1294–95 (2016). Although Maryland’s RTO, PJM, ran a capacity market to ensure future resource adequacy throughout the region, 254 See Conn. Dep’t of Pub. Util. Control v. FERC, 569 F.3d 477, 480 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (describing PJM’s capacity market). Maryland was frus­trated that the market was not incentivizing any generation to locate in congested areas of the state, where electricity prices were higher than average. 255 See Hughes, 136 S. Ct. at 1294. To attract new investment, Maryland “solicited proposals from various companies for construction of a new gas-fired power plant at a particular location.” 256 Id. It then entered into a “contract for differences” with the winning bidder, in which it guaranteed the winner a certain price for any capacity it supplied that also cleared the PJM capacity mar­ket auction. 257 Id.

The Supreme Court had no trouble finding that this scheme vio­lated the Supremacy Clause of the Constitution, as Maryland’s program “set[] an interstate wholesale rate” and thus “invade[d] FERC’s regula­tory turf” under the Federal Power Act. 258 Id. at 1297. The decision was 8-0, with two concurrences only “to emphasize the narrowness of the holding.” Hammond, supra note 35. In so holding, the Court was careful to point out that states “of course” maintain authority to “encour­age construction of new in-state generation.” 259 Hughes, 136 S. Ct. at 1298. The particular problem with Maryland’s scheme, though, was that the payments to the generator were “conditioned on [its] capacity clearing the auction,” such that they were too closely linked to interstate wholesale prices. 260 Id. at 1297 n.9. In contrast, the Court passed no judgment on “the permissibility of various other measures States might employ to encourage development of new or clean generation, including tax incentives, land grants, direct subsidies, construction of state-owned generation facilities, or reregulation of the energy sector.” 261 Id. at 1299.

Particularly given this explicit disclaimer, it is hard to know exactly what Hughes portends for the host of policies that states have designed to decarbonize electricity. 262 See Hammond, supra note 35 (arguing that Hughes “combines an easily predicta­ble result on the merits with significant uncertainty for states going forward”). There is now a profusion of litigation challeng­ing state clean-energy policies under Hughes’ logic. Both Illinois and New York are in the middle of litigation over the legality of their ZEC pro­grams. 263 See Coal. for Competitive Elec. v. Zibelman, 272 F. Supp. 3d 554 (S.D.N.Y. 2017), appeal docketed, No. 17-2654 (2d Cir. Aug. 25, 2017); Vill. of Old Mill Creek v. Star, Nos. 17-cv-01163 & 17-cv-01164, 2017 WL 3008289 (N.D. Ill. July 14, 2017), appeal docketed sub nom. Elec. Power Supply Ass’n v. Star, No. 17-2445 (7th Cir. July 17, 2017). Connecticut, Massachusetts, and Rhode Island have all faced similar attacks against their procurement policies for specific clean-energy resources. 264 See Riggs v. Curran, 863 F.3d 6, 7–8 (1st Cir. 2017) (dismissing on procedural grounds a challenge to Rhode Island’s statute seeking to develop offshore wind); Allco Fin. Ltd. v. Klee, 861 F.3d 82, 86–87 (2d Cir. 2017); Town of Barnstable v. Berwick, 17 F. Supp. 3d 113, 120–22 (D. Mass. 2014), vacated as moot or unripe, 786 F.3d 130 (1st Cir. 2015) (dismissing a challenge to Massachusetts’s offshore wind-procurement scheme on the grounds that the relief sought was retroactive and therefore barred by the Eleventh Amendment).

Whether these policies will ultimately prove acceptable will come down to how circuit and district courts interpret and apply the standards articulated in Hughes. 265 Hammond, supra note 35 (“Hughes doesn’t really tell us which state initiatives will survive future Supremacy Clause challenges and which will fail.”). And courts will have to integrate the Hughes precedent with two other recent Supreme Court cases dealing with simi­lar topics: OneOK v. Learjet, Inc. 266 135 S. Ct. 1591 (2015). and FERC v. Electric Power Supply Ass’n. 267 136 S. Ct. 760 (2016). The Court’s 2016 decision in Electric Power Supply Ass’n affirmed FERC’s jurisdiction over any practice “directly affecting” wholesale rates, striking down states’ arguments that FERC had overreached its jurisdic­tion. 268 Id. at 760. The year before, in OneOK, the Court clarified that field preemp­tion of state energy law should turn on an analysis of the purpose of the state regulation, such that courts should examine “the target at which the state law aims in determining whether that law is pre-empted.” 269 OneOK, 135 S. Ct. at 1599 (emphasis omitted). Interestingly, though, the Court did not rely on OneOK’s test in deciding Hughes the following year.

For present purposes, the fallout of Hughes and related precedents is that there might be substantial consequences to ceding new powers to regional electricity markets. Hughes made clear that because Maryland had granted PJM the right to control resource adequacy in the region by running a capacity market, the state lost some of its ability to concur­rently strive to achieve the same goals. In contrast, right now RTOs claim no control over decarbonization. Quite the contrary: They specifically decry any obligation in this regard. But what if states were to grant their electricity-market operator control over decarbonization? Then, under the logic of Hughes and OneOK, states might be preempted from tying any state policies too closely to whatever market construct for decarbon­ization the RTO devised. In particular, states would have to be careful not to impermissibly “tether” their policies or prices for clean energy to the results of regional clean-energy or carbon markets. 270 See Hughes v. Talen Energy Mktg., LLC, 136 S. Ct. 1288, 1299 (2016) (“Nothing in this opinion should be read to foreclose Maryland and other States from encouraging production of new or clean generation through measures ‘untethered to a generator’s wholesale market participation.’” (quoting Brief for Respondents at 40, Hughes, 136 S. Ct. 1288 (Nos. 14-614, 14-623), 2016 WL 183803)).

To be sure, even if a state decided to allow decarbonization to pro­ceed through its RTO, many traditional state methods of encouraging decarbonization would likely not be threatened—including tax breaks, financial incentives, and straightforward subsidies. Although part of the picture, these methods have not emerged as the predominant tools that states use to regulate climate. Instead, the most important state policies are those that proceed through rate regulation, including RPSs, ZECs, regional carbon prices, procurement mandates, and ratepayer support of certain technologies. 271 See Rossi, Carbon Taxation, supra note 8, at 298–306. There is a reason that these policies predominate: They are funded not through general taxation but through the rate base. They are, in other words, a form of covert “taxation by regula­tion,” 272 Richard A. Posner, Taxation by Regulation, 2 Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. 22, 23 (1971) (describing the phenomenon of “internal subsidies,” where policy aims are accom­plished through the use of rate regulation); see also Rossi, Carbon Taxation, supra note 8, at 278–80 (explaining how these climate change-related tools are a new version of Posner’s classic internal subsidization). which serves as a more politically feasible way to meet decarbon­ization aims than direct taxation. 273 Whether rate regulation presents a superior mechanism for accomplishing decar­bonization as compared to more general taxation is a question beyond the scope of this Article. Rossi provides a partial defense of such policies in Carbon Taxation by Regulation, supra note 8. Rossi argues that carbon taxation by regulation can and does function as an effective—albeit fragmented—substitute for carbon regulation but suggests that several reforms would help it do so more effectively. See id. at 323–41.

Under the Hughes framework, these popular forms of “carbon taxa­tion by regulation” would be particularly threatened by RTO jurisdiction over decarbonization. Regional carbon-pricing and state procurement schemes would be at risk if they were designed in ways that pegged their pricing to market outcomes. 274 See Hughes, 136 S. Ct. at 1299. Even Renewable Portfolio Standards—the central mechanism of state clean-energy policy to date—might prove vulnerable under an expansive interpretation of Hughes, should a state wish to pursue an RPS design that differs from a regional clean-energy procurement market. 275 Part IV describes why an expansive reading of Hughes, of the sort that would inval­idate RPSs, is unlikely. Nevertheless, the concern is a live one, even absent RTO subsumma­tion of decarbonization goals. Several parties in the ZEC litigation have worried that if ZECs are illegal, so too are RPSs. See Joel Eisen, The New (Clear?) Electricity Federalism: Federal Preemption of States’ “Zero Emissions Credit” Programs, 45 Ecology L.Q. (forthcoming 2018) (manuscript at 18) [hereinafter Eisen, Electricity Federalism] (on file with the Columbia Law Review) (collecting commentators raising this concern). Many participants in the ZEC litigation, however, assert that ZECs are different in kind from RPSs and other state policies. See Proposed Brief of Amicus Curiae American Wind Energy Ass’n in Support of Neither Party at 2, Elec. Power Supply Ass’n v. Star, No. 1:17-cv-01163 (N.D. Ill. Apr. 13, 2017). In his forthcoming article, Professor Joel Eisen argues for a reading of Hughes and related cases that would invalidate ZECs but allow state RPS policies to stand. See Eisen, Electricity Federalism, supra (manuscript at 19) (“ZECs aim directly at remedy­ing the revenue shortfall on the wholesale markets. RECs do not, because they are designed with reference to environmental attributes, not wholesale market prices.”).

A hypothetical example helps illustrate these concerns. Consider the case in which a state wishes to promote a particular type of renewable resource in the state that its RPS is inadequately incentivizing—say, off­shore wind. Right now, in order to promote more offshore wind, a state would be free to offer that generator a long-term premium on top of REC prices that fluctuates based on how much the generator is able to earn from the REC market. 276 See WSPP Inc., 139 FERC ¶ 61,061 (Apr. 20, 2012), 2012 WL 1395532, at *4 (find­ing that the separate sale of RECs does not fall within the Commission’s jurisdiction). The state might find this particular method for promoting certain renewables quite attractive, as it would create long-term investor certainty without complicating the state’s RPS or causing residents to overpay. 277 See supra note 95. But if renewables procurement were to become RTO administered and FERC jurisdictional (through proposals such as a regional clean-energy market), it is unclear whether such a scheme would survive. It might, under the logic of Hughes and OneOK, be too closely tethered in purpose or effect to the newly FERC-jurisdic­tional clean-energy market.

Less hypothetically, consider New York’s current study of adopting a single-state RTO carbon adder. There, regulators have proposed that a market carbon price and the state REC program can and should operate simultaneously. 278 Newell et al., supra note 194, at iv (“We assume the carbon charge is designed to com­plement (rather than replace) . . . existing policies that contribute to decarbonization.”). To facilitate this dual scheme, an August 2017 study by the Brattle Group proposed that “[f]uture REC contracts could be struc­tured so that the price adjusts automatically with changes in carbon prices, mitigating regulatory uncertainty associated with a carbon charge.” 279 Id. at 46. Again, under the logic of Hughes, it is not clear that such teth­ering would be permissible. 280 The legality of this proposal might turn on structural details, including the extent to which the state required such automatic price-adjustment mechanisms in REC contracting.

Of course, the risks that Hughes and related decisions pose remain largely inchoate. As such, it is hard to know how to factor them into pressing decisions on decarbonization policy and markets. This Article’s final section clarifies how states might integrate these developing risks into decisionmaking about the future of their climate change policies.

IV. Implications for Current Electricity-Law Debates

So far, this Article has explored some dangers in using regional elec­tricity markets as a tool to accomplish the “social project” of decarboniza­tion. At the same time, the Article does not intend to give short shrift to these markets’ potency as a potential least-cost solution or as a bargaining tool in interstate climate negotiations. To evaluate these tradeoffs, section IV.A first lays out some variables to help states assess whether regional electricity-market integra­tion of decarbonization objectives is in their best interest. Sections IV.B and IV.C then briefly explore options for regionalizing climate policy outside RTOs and how markets might adapt to accommodate such schemes. Finally, section IV.D examines what this Article’s argu­ment portends for laggard states, as opposed to states taking the lead on climate change.

A. Deciding Whether to Regionalize Through Electricity Markets

The limitations and pathologies of regional electricity markets iden­tified in this Article suggest that states should assess three variables in deciding whether to aggressively pursue the integration of climate goals into these markets: (1) the relative priority of advancing least-cost solutions; (2) the evolution of legal doctrine surrounding federal–state jurisdiction over electricity policy; and (3) regional politics.

1. Relative Priority of Least-Cost Solutions. — Much of this Article’s anal­ysis has centered on the ways in which state climate policies evince an understanding of decarbonization as a social project with multifaceted goals. State climate policies illustrate attention to distributional conse­quences, the risks and externalities associated with various low-carbon technologies, and the ways in which transforming energy can also trans­form state economies. But leading states are also pursuing ambi­tious targets, which are likely to cost substantial sums to achieve. 281 See Ron Binz et al., Practicing Risk-Aware Electricity Regulation: What Every State Regulator Needs to Know 5–6 (2012), http://www.raponline.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/05/ceres-binzsedano-riskawareregulation-2012-apr-19.pdf [http://perma.cc/5RJQ-DQF5] (predicting that retail electricity prices will “rise sharply” in the next twenty years due to the level of investment needed in the U.S. electricity sec­tor); James H. Williams et al., Pathways to Deep Decarbonization in the United States 1, 24 (2014), http://unsdsn.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/09/US-Deep-Decarbonization-Report.pdf [http://perma.cc/W45R-MF7Z] (estimating the median price of cutting car­bon dioxide emissions 80% from 1990 levels by 2050 to be between $160 billion and $650 billion). It could be that as implementation progresses, affordability will become the dominant priority for states pursuing decarbonization.

Accordingly, the first question state policymakers considering regional integration might ask is: How important is least-cost decarboniza­tion to state residents, as compared to a more managed decarbonization trajectory that incorporates other goals? The more the scale tilts in favor of affordability as a central criterion, the greater the benefits of regional­ization through electricity markets.

Understanding decarbonization as a social project also points to some useful conclusions about what kind of regional market design for decarbonization states might prefer. In particular, a Forward Clean Energy Market in which states can funnel their decarbonization prefer­ences into the market design presents less of a relinquishment of state control than does a region-wide climate price. 282 See supra section III.A for a detailed description of these two policy options. Of course, a clean-energy market also presents a less thoroughly efficient solution—again highlighting the importance of prioritizing state aims relating to decarbonization.

One final word regarding temporality is in order. Even if a state finds that a particular market construct for achieving decarbonization might perfectly achieve its aims at time zero, there is a long-term risk to ceding such control to the market. Given the scale of the enterprise of deep decarbonization, a state’s goals and preferences regarding the shape of decarbonization may well evolve over time. 283 See, e.g., Weiner, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 159, at 5 (expressing concern that wholesale market integration of climate policy “would likely hinder States in adapting to changing times”); cf. Mhairi Aitken, Why We Still Don’t Understand the Social Aspects of Wind Power: A Critique of Key Assumptions Within the Literature, 38 Energy Pol’y 1834, 1835 (2010) (noting research that regarding nuclear power plants, “public attitudes are not stable but rather adapt and change in relation to events or changing situations”). If state aims change such that affordability ceases to be the priority criterion, a state may have lim­ited recourse once it has ceded decarbonization imperatives to the mar­ket, other than full-scale market exit.

This temporal constraint appears particularly acute with respect to carbon-pricing schemes, which may “lock in” investments that states do not want their ratepayers to support. 284 See generally Karen C. Seto et al., Carbon Lock-in: Types, Causes, and Policy Implications, 41 Ann. Rev. Env’t. & Resources 425 (2016) (describing the path-dependent processes that prevent the emergence of low-carbon alternatives). A regional carbon price would likely incentivize near-term investments in new combined-cycle natural gas facilities, which could displace higher-emitting fossil fuel facilities. 285 See Newell et al., supra note 194, at 33. But states may not want a carbon-price scheme to help finance construc­tion of these types of facilities, given their inability to contribute to long-term “deep decarbonization” targets. 286 Cf. Liscow & Karpilow, supra note 168, at 421–22 (suggesting reasons for states to target a few promising cleantech options in their climate investment). States weighing market integra­tion should thus carefully evaluate not only short-term goals but also the compatibility of a market scheme with their long-term aims.

2. Evolving Legal Risk. — The second variable that can help shape state decisions regarding decarbonization and electricity markets is that of evolving legal risk. As traced in section III.E, the Hughes decision has opened up a new line of attack on state climate policies. How these cases play out in the coming years should influence decisions about whether to decarbonize through regional markets.

Consider first the outcome in which courts give Hughes its narrowest possible reading. Courts in this instance would hold that Hughes preempts only those state policies that explicitly condition receipt of some benefit on clearing wholesale electricity markets. 287 Cf. Vill. of Old Mill Creek v. Star, Nos. 17-cv-01163 & 17-cv-01164, 2017 WL 3008289, at *13 (N.D. Ill. July 14, 2017), appeal docketed sub nom. Elec. Power Supply Ass’n v. Star, No. 17-2445 (7th Cir. July 17, 2017) (“Hughes should not be extended to invalidate state laws that do not include an express condition, but that in practice (and when combined with other market forces), have the effect of conditioning payment on clearing the wholesale auction.”). In that case, states might feel more confident in ceding some authority over decarboniza­tion to regional electricity markets, because they could assume such shared authority would place limited constraints upon state power. A state in this scenario would likely maintain considerable ability to shape its decarbon­ization trajectory, so long as complementary state policies were not explicitly conditioned on certain regional decarbonization mar­ket outcomes.

Now consider the (in my opinion, less likely 288 See Peskoe, supra note 35, at 41 (“Renewable portfolio standards . . . have co-existed with FERC-regulated markets for nearly two decades with little significant legal controversy.”); supra note 276. ) outcome in which courts use the logic of Hughes to strike down RPSs, nuclear subsidies, and special procurement orders as intruding on federal jurisdiction over regional electricity markets. In that case, states would be faced with a conundrum. On the one hand, states would be left with considerably fewer climate policy options other than using regional electricity markets, since their primary policy levers to date would be impermissible. On the other hand, a decision to cede decarbonization objectives to the market would likely take even more policy options off the table, given that Hughes and its progeny in this scenario would stand for the proposition that states are prohibited from enacting a broad range of policies that too thoroughly impact regional markets. In this case, states would be faced with difficult choices between returning to the drawing board in terms of how to craft state climate policies, or giving in to the pressure to let the markets do their decarbonization work for them.

Finally, consider the emerging middle-ground scenario, in which courts develop a sliding scale for determining which state policies are too closely “tethered” to wholesale markets. 289 Hughes v. Talen Energy Mktg., LLC, 136 S. Ct. 1288, 1299 (2016). Early indications are that courts are likely to head in this direction. In June 2017, the Second Circuit became the first circuit court to interpret Hughes, ruling on a challenge to Connecticut’s use of its procurement laws to encourage more solar energy. 290 See Allco Fin. Ltd. v. Klee, 861 F.3d 82, 86 (2d Cir. 2017). The plaintiff in that case argued that Connecticut’s procurement scheme should be preempted under the logic of Hughes, since the state was directing its utilities to enter into a specific wholesale contract and therefore interfering with federal jurisdiction over wholesale electricity pricing. 291 See id. at 86, 92. The Second Circuit dodged the direct preemption argument, instead finding that Connecticut’s law did not compel utilities to enter into contracts with the winning bidders of the procurement process. 292 See id. at 97–98. The court thus left open the question of whether a state scheme that more clearly required utilities to enter into contracts with certain renewable resources would be preempted. Never­theless, the court took a moment to opine on Hughes, observing that Connecticut’s scheme appears quite different from Maryland’s failed pro­gram, given that Connecticut’s program involves traditional bilateral con­tracts that are in no way conditioned on certain resources clearing the regional capacity auction. 293 Id. at 99, 102. As such, Connecticut’s contracts resemble “precisely what the Hughes court placed outside its limited holding.” 294 Id. at 99.

In July 2017, U.S. District Courts for the Northern District of Illinois and the Southern District of New York reached similarly limited conclu­sions in dismissing lawsuits against Illinois’s and New York’s ZEC pro­grams. 295 Coal. for Competitive Elec. v. Zibelman, 272 F. Supp. 3d 554, 571 (S.D.N.Y. 2017), appeal docketed, No. 17-2654 (2d Cir. Aug. 25, 2017); Vill. of Old Mill Creek v. Star, Nos. 17-cv-1163 & 17-cv-1164, 2017 WL 3008289, at *1 (N.D. Ill. July 14, 2017), appeal docketed sub nom. Elec. Power Supply Ass’n v. Star, No. 17-2445 (7th Cir. July 17, 2017). The first opinion to be issued concerned Illinois. Plaintiffs in that case argued, inter alia, that the ZEC program violated the Hughes standard for preemption because it was too closely tied to wholesale prices, since Illinois’s program allowed for the price of ZECs to be adjusted based on predictions of wholesale prices. 296 Star, 2017 WL 3008289, at *4, *10. The court rejected this argument, reasoning that basing ZEC prices on future projected wholesale prices is not an interference with the wholesale market that rises to the level of Hughes. 297 Id. at *11. The court also rejected an argument that receipt of ZECs was implicitly tied to participation in wholesale markets. Id. at *12–13.

The Southern District of New York reached the same conclusion regarding that state’s program. Its opinion emphasized that Hughes was focused on the “impermissible tether” of required participation in the wholesale market and that New York’s ZEC program required nothing of the sort. 298 Zibelman, 272 F. Supp. 3d at 569. Moreover, the court observed, the ZEC program “does not guarantee a certain wholesale price that displaces the market-determined price” but rather simply places a separate value on the environmental attributes of nuclear. 299 Id. at *17. For this reason, the court found the scheme indistinguishable from RPS and RECs, which it noted FERC has long determined fall outside its jurisdiction. Id. at *13.

The Illinois and New York decisions have been appealed to the Seventh and Second Circuits, respectively. 300 Zibelman, 272 F. Supp. 3d 554, appeal docketed, No. 17-2654 (2d Cir. Aug. 25, 2017); Star, 2017 WL 3008289, appeal docketed, No. 17-2445 (7th Cir. July 18, 2017). These courts are now tasked with drawing a delicate line between schemes that come too close to elec­tricity markets in design or in purpose 301 On the “purpose” point, it is interesting to note that both courts highlighted this line of inquiry from OneOK and emphasized the extent to which the state ZEC programs had environmental goals that were quite distinct from wholesale-market aims. See Zibelman, 272 F. Supp. 3d at 571; Star, 2017 WL 3008289, at *10–11. and those that stay further away from pegging their schemes to market prices and functions. The fact that this jurisprudence appears to be shaping itself around this inquiry should at least give states pause about ceding control over decarbonization to the markets. In doing so, states risk carving out more room for their poli­cies to become constrained by regional markets’ integration of the pro­ject of decarbonization.

3. Regional Politics. — One final variable relevant to state decisionma­king on integrating climate change aims into regional electricity mar­kets is that of regional politics. This Article painted regional electricity-market governance as suffering from pathologies that are likely to yield least-common-denominator solutions. 302 See supra sections III.B–.C. This potentiality is least prob­lematic in one-state RTOs like New York. That state is more likely to be able to translate its climate goals into a market-based scheme that fully reflects its decarbonization aims—leaving one fewer variable for state regulators there to contend with. 303 Such is particularly the case if state regulators retain control over establishing the level of carbon pricing. Cf. Newell et al., supra note 194, at 22 (dodging the political ques­tion of how New York’s price might be set in noting that “[p]olicymakers should define a process for determining the price and modifying it over time” and that “[t]his process could be led or informed by the NYPSC and other state agencies”). In multistate regions, though, the challenge of watering down is quite real. But even there, perhaps aggres­sive states might use market integration as a bargaining chip in negotia­tions with other states that are worried about state climate policies’ desta­bilizing effects on the regional market. In particular, they might suggest to a recalcitrant state: “Up the ambition of your RPS five percent, or allow the market to use a higher price on carbon, and we will commit to pursuing regional decarbonization through the market.” It is not clear whether laggard states see enough appeal to using electricity markets that such a promise could motivate them to greater action on climate change. But the more states find this outcome plausible, the more appealing using regional electricity markets to decarbonize might be.

B. Thinking Outside the Market: State-Led Climate Policy Regionalization

Much of the appeal of using regional electricity markets to accom­plish climate change aims comes from the opportunity they present for capitalizing on the efficiencies of a larger, regional market construct. But if that’s the draw for states, then electricity markets are far from the only method available. Many states have already devised regional solutions through cooperative arrangements that avoid the pathologies of electric­ity markets. 304 See Sarah Hofmann, Comm’r, Vt. Pub. Serv. Bd., Exec. Comm. Nat’l Council on Elec. Policy (NCEP), Statement at FERC Technical Conference: State Policies and Wholesale Markets Operated by ISO-New England, Inc., New York Independent System Operator, Inc. and PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., at 3 (May 1, 2017), http://electricitypolicy.org/
wp-content/uploads/sites/6/2017/05/Statement-of-Commissioner-Hofmann-for-FERC-tech-conference-on-Ma-1.pdf
[http://perma.cc/89QD-L2HX] (argu­ing to FERC that states “are well suited to collaboratively working out answers to the policy questions”).

Two successful examples predominate. 305 States were also actively pursuing regional solutions to Clean Power Plan compli­ance until the Trump Administration announced plans to dismantle these regulations. See Susan F. Tierney & Paul J. Hibbard, Analysis Grp., Carbon Control and Competitive Wholesale Electricity Markets: Compliance Paths for Efficient Market Outcomes 22–26 (2015), http://www.analysisgroup.com/uploadedfiles/content/insights/publishing/clean_
power_plan_markets_may_2015_final.pdf
[http://perma.cc/DEY4-WC2B] (encour­aging states to adopt regional Clean Power Plan compliance plans that track market borders); see also Exec. Order No. 13,783, 82 Fed. Reg. 16,093, 16,095 (Mar. 31, 2017) (instructing the EPA Administrator to review the Clean Power Plan with an eye toward withdrawal).
The first is a regional cap-and-trade program, the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI), which nine northeastern states have been running since 2009. 306 See RGGI, supra note 75. In this scheme, participating states devised a “memorandum of understanding” that set forth negotiated carbon-reduction targets for each state, along with a plan for each state to adopt legislation approving of the regional scheme. 307 RGGI, Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative: Memorandum of Understanding 1–11 (2005), http://www.rggi.org/docs/mou_12_20_05.pdf [http://perma.cc/PVB6-BL3Y]; see also Craig, supra note 85, at 821 (explaining RGGI’s structure). All states were able to pass such legislation, bringing the scheme into force. Under the program as it is currently run, each genera­tor that emits carbon pollution must purchase enough credits to cover its emissions from a region-wide auction. 308 Fact Sheet: RGGI CO2 Allowance Auctions, RGGI, http://www.rggi.org/docs/RGGI_
Auctions_in_Brief.pdf [http://perma.cc/6YQB-MD23] (last visited Jan. 20, 2018).

RGGI has coexisted for almost ten years alongside the PJM, NYISO, and ISO-New England regional electricity markets with scant complaints regarding market interference. Generators simply factor the cost of RGGI allowances into their expenses, on which they base their bids into regional electricity markets. 309 See Peskoe, supra note 35, at 44. Peskoe notes, however, that RGGI, too, might face increased risk of preemption if participating states pursue a FERC-jurisdictional car­bon price. See id. Clearly this requirement to at least par­tially internalize the costs of carbon emissions has an impact on the prices at which these generators offer electricity to the regional markets, but no one argues that it creates a distortionary effect. 310 See Tierney & Hibbard, supra note 305, at 25 (asserting that RGGI “allows for seamless implementation in centralized wholesale power markets”). RGGI thus stands as proof that it is possible to concoct a regional pricing scheme outside the regional electricity market without causing undue interference.

RGGI is not an unmitigated success—otherwise, many of its partici­pants would hardly now be considering building carbon pricing into their regional electricity markets. RGGI’s main problem, quite simply, is that the caps that states were able to agree upon for RGGI—and the resultant allowance prices—have been too low to accomplish the most ambitious states’ decarbonization goals. 311 See Memorandum of Law, supra note 154, at 6 n.12 (“[T]he RGGI program is not sufficient to meet New York’s 50 percent renewables and 40 percent [greenhouse gas] reduction goals, and changing RGGI to achieve more ambitious goals ‘is not within the State’s unilateral control.’” (citation omitted) (quoting Clean Energy Standard Order, supra note 99, at 133)). Nevertheless, RGGI has functioned as a base policy upon which states can build the myriad other decarboniza­tion policies discussed in this Article. And RGGI can function in this manner because a regional “memorandum of understanding” creates no risk of wresting away state power to address decarbonization simultane­ously at the state level. At the same time, building upon years of trust among states, RGGI has twice succeeded in lowering its program carbon cap, thus raising the cost of allowance prices and strengthening the program’s effects. 312 See RGGI, Summary of RGGI Model Rule Changes: February 2013, at 3 (2013), http://www.rggi.org/sites/default/files/Uploads/Design-Archive/Model-Rule/2012-Program-Review-Update/Summary_of_Model_Rule_Changes_02_07_13.pdf [http://perma.cc/BDS4-P46G]; Dale Bryk, East Coast States Strengthen Power Plant Pollution-Cutting Program, Set Model for Nation, NRDC Expert Blog (Feb. 7, 2013), http://www.nrdc.org/experts/
dale-bryk/east-coast-states-strengthen-power-plant-pollution-cutting-program-set-model [http://perma.cc/56SH-4SJH]; Bruce Ho & Jackson Morris, RGGI Agrees to Cut Power Plant Pollution by Another 30%, NRDC Expert Blog (Aug. 23, 2017), http://www.nrdc.org/experts/bruce-ho/rggi-agrees-cut-power-plant-pollution-another-30 [http://perma.cc/V5BH-WW39].
RGGI’s structure thus presents an appealing alterna­tive to electricity-market integration for states intent on regionalization.

A second example of regional cooperation on decarbonization out­side of electricity markets comes from regional trading of RECs—the renewable energy credits that utilities use to demonstrate compliance with state RPS. 313 See supra notes 85–86 and accompanying text. To date, most REC markets are single state—thus creating what many critics have bemoaned as unnecessarily constricted trading pools. 314 See Crandall, supra note 86, at 896; Davies, Power Forward, supra note 84, at 1343–44; Mack et al., supra note 86, at 18; Mormann, supra note 36, at 1644–45. But the New England states have created a regional market for RECs that enlarges the pool of RECs available to create a more stable, fluid market. 315 See, e.g., Conn. Gen. Stat. § 16-245a(b) (2017); see also Allco Fin. Ltd. v. Klee, 861 F.3d 82, 89–90 (2d Cir. 2017) (describing the program); Mack et al., supra note 86, at 20 (same). They have done so through state laws that allow for gen­erators to satisfy state RPS obligations with RECs purchased from any generator in the region that meets the state-specific definition of “renew­able,” or similarly, from a renewable generator outside the New England region that can demonstrate that its renewable energy was imported into the region. 316 See, e.g., Vt. Pub. Serv. Dep’t, Types of Renewable Energy Credits in New England: A Summary 1 (2015) (on file with the Columbia Law Review). A renewable energy generator outside the region can satisfy this requirement with help from a regional track­ing system that monitors the renewable energy imported from surrounding ISOs and other entities. See id.; see also Klee, 861 F.3d at 92. In this way, New England already orchestrates regional cooperation on renewable energy.

These programs suggest that regional cooperation can flourish with­out having to relinquish control to quasi-private governance organiza­tions that are not under state oversight. To be sure, both RGGI and New England’s REC-sharing arrangement carry their own legal risk. Commentators frequently point to the dangers of both the Compact Clause 317 The Compact Clause prohibits states from entering “into any Agreement or Compact with another State” without the consent of Congress. U.S. Const. art. I, § 10. But not all compacts are prohibited—the critical question, as formulated by the Supreme Court in U.S. Steel Corp. v. Multistate Tax Comm’n, 434 U.S. 452, 493 (1978), is whether the agreement increases the “political power” of participating states. and the Dormant Commerce Clause 318 The Dormant Commerce Clause prohibits states from enacting measures grounded in economic protectionism, which “benefit in-state economic interests by bur­dening out-of-state competitors.” Dep’t of Revenue v. Davis, 553 U.S. 328, 338 (2008) (internal quotation marks omitted) (quoting New Energy Co. of Ind. v. Limbach, 486 U.S. 269, 273–74 (1988)). when it comes to pro­grams like these. 319 See, e.g., Craig, supra note 85, at 771, 786, 820 (highlighting potential constitu­tional infirmities with RGGI and regional RECs); Note, The Compact Clause and the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, 120 Harv. L. Rev. 1958, 1965 (2007). See generally Ferrey et al., supra note 92 (examining constitutional challenges to a feed-in tariff for renewable power).

These risks are not theoretical—both RGGI and the New England REC program have faced lawsuits on these grounds. 320 See North Dakota v. Heydinger, 825 F.3d 912, 920–21 (8th Cir. 2016) (striking down Minnesota’s law providing that “‘no person’ shall ‘import or commit to import’ power from a large new energy facility located ‘outside the state’” on Dormant Commerce Clause grounds). But for now, courts have sided with the states. One New York case brought against RGGI on Compact Clause grounds settled; 321 See Consent Decree, Indeck Corinth, L.P. v. Paterson, No. 5280-09 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. Dec. 23, 2009) (on file with the Columbia Law Review); Christopher Rizzo, Cap-and-Trade Under Attack Around the Nation, GreenLaw Blog (June 29, 2011), http://greenlaw.blogs.pace.edu/2011/06/29/cap-and-trade-under-attack-around-the-nation [http://perma.cc/TS9E-AA6N] (providing a report of the settlement). another was thrown out on procedural grounds. 322 Thrun v. Cuomo, 976 N.Y.S.2d 320, 322 (Sup. Ct. 2013) (dismissing the case because “certain claims are time-barred and the remaining claims have been rendered moot”). New England’s regional REC scheme recently received substantial validation on Dormant Commerce Clause grounds, in the same Second Circuit opinion that upheld the state’s renewables procurement regime. 323 Allco Fin. Ltd. v. Klee, 861 F.3d 82, 86–87 (2d Cir. 2017). Plaintiffs alleged that the New England regional REC-sharing program harmed their interests in a Georgia solar facility, which was not allowed to sell RECs to Connecticut utilities for purposes of RPS compliance. The Second Circuit found no merit in this contention, determining that a Georgia REC and a New England REC are in fact “different products” that can legally be treated differently. Id. at 103. Underlying this finding was the recognition that “Connecticut consumers’ need for a more diversified and renewable energy supply, acces­sible to them directly through their regional grid or indirectly through adjacent control areas, would not be served by RECs produced . . . in Georgia.” Id. at 105. With these holdings in place, both a regional cap-and-trade program and a regional market for RECs appear to stand on relatively firm legal ground. Of course, it could still come to pass that RPS programs themselves get struck down or that another circuit ana­lyzes regional RECs’ constitutionality differently. But the legal risk inher­ent in pursuing these types of regional solutions comes for states with an attendant gain—not having to relinquish public control over the course and content of these important decarbonization programs.

C. Designing Markets to Accommodate, Rather than Achieve, State Policies

The problem, of course, with pursuing regional solutions outside markets is that it returns the states to the problem animating current dis­putes: the fact that extra-market solutions, whether pursued at the regional or state level, may distort and ultimately dismantle electricity markets. 324 See supra section I.C. Here, then, a separate set of proposals for how to manage these concerns is salient. While many are deep in exploration of how to use electricity markets to achieve decarbonization, there is a second strand of proposed reforms that would focus on redesigning electricity markets not to subsume state climate policies but merely to accommodate them. Such accommodation would require regional markets to embrace the coexistence of manifold state policies in a way that has not always been the case to date and to intentionally mold their rules to support the con­tinued viability of markets in the face of these state policies. 325 To be fair, regions have already been doing some accommodation for years, through policies such as exemptions from the “minimum offer price rule,” Kavulla, supra note 56, which requires that “new generators bid . . . at or above a specified price in certain circumstances,” Rossi, Brave New Path, supra note 36, at 424. See also N.J. Bd. of Pub. Utils. v. FERC, 744 F.3d 74, 85–86, 93–94 (3d Cir. 2014) (describing the minimum offer price rule and upholding PJM’s determination not to exempt state-supported resources from it any longer). But the current suite of accommodations is clearly inade­quate, given the worries documented about wholesale market interference in this Article.

There are many ideas about how markets might be refined to better accommodate state climate policies, and most proposals tend to be quite technical. The basic idea behind them, though, is this: Regions should identify what current market signals are failing to achieve, and rework the market construct to achieve these aims. That might be through pric­ing some “attribute” of electricity that markets do not currently value—for example, markets might pay generators for their ability to “ramp” up and down quickly to balance out renewables. 326 MISO and CAISO have introduced “ramping products,” which compensate resources for their ability to ramp up and down quickly. Chang et al., supra note 119, at 25. To read more about how other markets might pursue similar programs, see PJM, Proposed Enhancements to Energy Price Formation 2, 5 (2017), http://www.pjm.com/-/media/
library/reports-notices/special-reports/20171115-proposed-enhancements-to-energy-price-formation.ashx [http://perma.cc/7UGN-BVE7]. Cf. Hogan, supra note 121, at 8 (pointing out some of the challenges with this strategy).
Or, it might be through redesigning capacity markets to pay different prices to state-supported resources—like renewables and nuclear energy—and resources that are unsupported by these policies. 327 See PJM, Capacity Market Repricing Proposal 1 (2017) [hereinafter PJM, Repricing Proposal], http://pjm.com/~/media/library/reports-notices/special-reports/20170502-
capacity-market-repricing-proposal.ashx/ [http://perma.cc/K2UQ-CB3P] (pro­posing a “two-stage capacity auction” in which state-supported resources are allowed to clear the market but do not set the price to be paid to other resources); Peskoe, supra note 35, at 16 (detailing these proposals); see also NEPOOL, Framework Document Two-Tier FCM Pricing 1–2 (2016), http://nepool.com/uploads/IMAPP_20160914_Framework_NRG_
r
ev.pdf [http://perma.cc/GND8-FM36] (describing a two-stage forward capac­ity auction); CMEEC, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 240, at 4 (proposing alternatively a “bilateral-residual capacity market structure”); American Municipal Power, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 112, at 4 (same). Identifying what counts as “state sup­port” and what doesn’t is likely to be a contentious area for negotiation under this pro­posal. See PJM, Repricing Proposal, supra, at 4 (describing how PJM will distinguish “actionable from non-actionable subsidies”); Chen, FERC Technical Conference, supra note 112, at 1 (worrying these proposals will unfairly focus on the “more visible” state policies for renewables).

The Department of Energy’s October 2017 proposed “Grid Resiliency Pricing Rule” can be understood as one such attempt to refine market structures 328 See Grid Resiliency Pricing Rule, 82 Fed. Reg. 46,940, 46,941–45 (proposed Oct. 10, 2017) (to be codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35). —albeit, in the view of many experts, a poorly designed one. In that notice of proposed rulemaking, the Department asked FERC to consider providing out-of-market payments to “fuel-secure” resources that it believes are undervalued by current regional market-pricing structures. 329 Id. at 46,945. In particular, this proposed rule would have provided additional compensation to coal and nuclear plants in recognition of the “resiliency” benefits 330 The concept of “grid resiliency” lacks a clear definition. The National Academy of Sciences has explained it in this way: “Resilience is not just about lessening the likeli­hood that [grid] outages will occur. It is also about limiting the scope and impact of out­ages when they do occur, restoring power rapidly afterwards, and learning from these experiences to better deal with events in the future.” Comm. on Enhancing the Resilience of the Nation’s Elec. Power Transmission and Distribution Sys., Nat’l Acad. Sci., Enhancing the Resilience of the Nation’s Electricity System 1 (2017), http://www.naesb.org/misc/nas_
report.pdf
[http://perma.cc/JH9W-DPEU]. In DOE’s proposed rule, the agency “does not define ‘resiliency,’ nor has the Commission ever used that word in connection with wholesale rates.” Harvard Environmental Policy Initiative, Comments on Proposed Grid Resiliency Pricing Rule, FERC Docket No. RM18-1-000, at 1 (Oct. 18, 2017), http://
environment.law.harvard.edu/wp-content/uploads/2017/10/Harvard-EPI-DOE-NOPR-Comment.pdf [http://perma.cc/YA3N-PVXD].
that substantial on-site storage of fuel can provide. 331 See Grid Resiliency Pricing Rule, 82 Fed. Reg. at 46,942–43. Note, however, that the DOE NOPR differs from state nuclear support schemes in one critical way: It does not recognize the climate change benefits of nuclear power in the least.

In January 2018, FERC terminated this proposed rulemaking, explaining that the proposal was legally insufficient because it failed to demonstrate that regions were experiencing any resiliency challenges that resulted in “unjust and unreasonable” RTO tariffs. 332 See Order Terminating Rulemaking Proceeding, Initiating New Proceeding, and Establishing Additional Procedures, 162 FERC ¶ 61,012 (Jan. 8, 2018), 2018 WL 345249, at *5. In FERC’s termination order, several commissioners sharply critiqued the Department of Energy’s plan for its potential to unravel energy markets. In particular, they suggested that the Department had used the amor­phous goal of “resiliency” to justify payments to two favored resources that do not clearly provide grid resiliency benefits, while ignoring other resources that might better provide grid resiliency. 333 See id. at *12 (LaFleur, Comm’r, concurring); id. at *16 (Glick, Comm’r, concurring); Comments of the PUC of the State of California, Grid Reliability and Resilience Pricing, FERC Docket No. RM18-1-000, at 1, 4–6 (Oct. 23, 2017) (“Evidence regarding reliability in the electricity industry cannot support the argument that baseload power is the central means for providing reliability and resiliency.”); Chang et al., supra note 119, at 16–17; Jody Freeman & Joseph Goffman, Opinion, Rick Perry’s Anti-Market Plan to Help Coal, N.Y. Times (Oct. 25, 2017), http://www.nytimes.com/2017/10/25/
opinion/rick-perry-coal-antimarket.html?_r=0
(on file with the Columbia Law Review) (“Selectively subsidizing coal and nuclear power is not the most obvious or best way to bolster the grid against sudden events.”).
In place of this mis­guided attempt, the Commission initiated a new rulemaking “to specifi­cally evaluate the resilience of the bulk power system in the regions oper­ated by [RTOs],” as a first step in determining whether there is a real need to redesign markets to respond to resiliency challenges. 334 Order Terminating Rulemaking Proceeding, Initiating New Proceeding, and Establishing Additional Procedures, 162 FERC ¶ 61,012, 2018 WL 345249, at *1.

Through these new twists, the Department of Energy’s controversial proposal could ultimately prompt regional solutions that strengthen markets while responding to concerns over ever-expanding state resource subsidization. A frank reckoning with exactly what “resilience” services are lacking from the grid and what resources and investments might pro­vide them should help regions determine if there is some “resiliency attribute” that markets currently undervalue and whether there is a mar­ket-grounded methodology for rewarding any resources that provide that value. 335 The comments of bipartisan former FERC commissioners on the DOE NOPR make a similar suggestion:
“We strongly encourage the Commission to use this opportunity created by the Secretary to identify attributes of the current competitive market system that need to be improved, to crisply define them and either modify the current published proposal or initiate regional proceedings to examine resilience issues and consider the need for market rule changes.”
Bipartisan Former FERC Commissioners, Comments on Proposed Grid Resiliency Pricing Rule, FERC Docket No. RM18-1-000, at 7 (Oct. 19, 2017), http://s3.amazonaws.com/dive_static/paychek/Comments_of_BFFC_Docket_RM18-1_1.pdf [http://perma.cc/8B34-GQV3].
If pursued in this manner, an RTO’s creation of an additional revenue stream for currently undervalued “resiliency” characteristics could help offset any resilience challenges that state-supported renewa­bles might pose for the grid. 336 Note that there is substantial disagreement as to whether renewables do in fact destabilize the grid. Many believe that state-supported renewables might actually enhance grid resiliency. See, e.g., Order Terminating Rulemaking Proceeding, Initiating New Proceeding, and Establishing Additional Procedures, 162 FERC ¶ 61,012, 2018 WL 345249, at *15 (Glick, Comm’r, concurring). At the same time, such a reform would not undermine state climate change goals and programs by selectively providing payments to the most carbon-polluting resource in the market: coal.

The Department of Energy’s proposed Grid Resilience Pricing Rule thus provides a sort of crossroads that underscores this Article’s argu­ment about why states should be cautious in ceding decarbonization to RTOs. At best, FERC may use the proposed rule as a jumping-off point for redesigning markets in a way that truly helps RTOs better accommo­date state climate change policies. If this path is taken, then state and regional policies will cause less friction for markets going forward—ren­dering robust state decarbonization policies less problematic. At worst, certain RTOs might use the proposed rule as an invitation to create their own subsidy schemes aimed at propping up aging coal and nuclear for reasons unrelated to climate change aims—and in large part, in direct contravention of them. 337 For example, in November 2017, the mid-Atlantic RTO, PJM, proposed a “price reformation” program that would allow for “inflexible” (that is, slow-ramping) units to set the market price so as to better reflect “the true incremental cost to serve load.” PJM, Proposed Enhancements to Energy Price Formation 1–2 (2017), http://www.pjm.com/-/
media/library/reports-notices/special-reports/20171115-proposed-enhancements-to-energy-price-formation.ashx
[http://perma.cc/HQ9P-NPBA] (defining “inflexible units” as “those with declining average costs that are unable to economically produce power within a certain range or that require an economic minimum output”). This proposal is more market oriented than the DOE-proposed rule, but it still differentiates resources based on “inflexibility” in ways that do not appear fully justified. PJM’s own market moni­tor opposes the proposal. See Catherine Tyler, Valuing Inflexibility Undermines Energy Price Formation, Monitoring Analytics 7–8 (2017), http://www.monitoringanalytics.com/reports/
Presentations/2017/IMM_PJM_Energy%20Policy_Roundtable_Valuing_Inflexibility_
Undermines_Energy_Price_Formation_20170927.pdf [http://perma.cc/YTN4-PHHX].
If this path is pursued, then states will likely be glad not to have even partially ceded the goal of decarbonization to these markets, only to have them work to actively undermine it.

These concerns—that RTOs and their participating states might end up with competing objectives—highlight another potential avenue of reform. Twenty-odd years ago, FERC created RTOs as a grand experi­ment in new ways to manage electricity. 338 See Regional Transmission Organizations, 65 Fed. Reg. 810, 811 (Dec. 20, 1999) (codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35) (establishing RTOs). But we have moved beyond the early, experimental stage of RTOs’ existence. If their initial governance structures turn out not to serve states well, perhaps it is time to consider not only tweaking market design to accommodate state policies but also more dramatically reforming RTO governance itself. There is not enough space in this section to consider the possibilities and practicalities of pursuing these larger reforms, but hopefully the concerns raised here will prompt fur­ther inquiries in this vein.

B. But What About the Laggards?

This Article focuses on a conundrum facing states that are leading the way in addressing climate change, arguing that they should cling to the right to shape their decarbonization trajectories. In articulating this argument, this Article has attempted to sketch the ways in which decar­bonization is a “social” project, requiring care in crafting its contours rather than merely its end game.

But the primary problem confronting state climate change policy today isn’t the underappreciated “social nature” of decarbonization. The bigger problem is the fact that a good many citizens—and state govern­ments—deny the existence of climate change and refuse to do much of anything to promote decarbonization. Laggard states not only do little to address climate change within their own boundaries but also actively impede efforts at federal climate change policies. 339 See, e.g., Samantha Page, 26 Attorneys General Are Suing the EPA. The Public Only Agrees with Them in 3 States, ThinkProgress (Nov. 3, 2015), http://thinkprogress.org/
26-attorneys-general-are-suing-the-epa-the-public-only-agrees-with-them-in-3-states-e935d36e42ba
[http://perma.cc/M9F6-U7D9] (providing a map of the twenty-six states suing the Environmental Protection Agency to halt implementation of the Obama Administration’s “Clean Power Plan” to address greenhouse gas emissions).

For those who care about action on climate change, then, this Article’s argument that we should leave states to shape their own policies might seem to create a critical downside: Leaving the aims of energy pol­icy to state legislators and regulators means accepting whatever ends they democratically determine, be they climate change goals or coal mine job preservation goals. Such risks are not hypothetical: Ohio has already pur­sued efforts to provide supplementary ratepayer funds to several coal plants at risk of retirement, 340 See Elec. Power Supply Ass’n v. AEP Generation Res., Inc., 155 FERC ¶ 61,102 (Apr. 27, 2016), 2016 WL 1717028, at *11–12 (rejecting an attempt by Ohio generators to pass through the costs of supporting certain in-state coal generation to captive ratepayers). and there is considerable interest under the present Administration in protecting “baseload power” from renewa­ble energy. 341 See Grid Resiliency Pricing Rule, 82 Fed. Reg. 46,940, 46,941–45 (Oct. 10, 2017) (to be codified at 18 C.F.R. pt. 35). This interest may prompt more states to enact policies that seek to support not particular clean-energy sources but particular dirty-energy sources. 342 See Kavulla, supra note 56 (observing that such state laws “are proliferat­ing, and they are not limited to renewables but whatever a legislature might prefer”).

Such is these states’ right in a federalist system with no overarching federal climate policy. 343 Of course, should the Clean Power Plan—the Obama-era regulation that sets greenhouse gas emissions reductions targets for each state—ultimately persist, it will act as a “floor” below which no state can go in terms of climate change policy. See Carbon Pollution Emission Guidelines for Existing Stationary Sources: Electric Utility Generating Units, 80 Fed. Reg. 64,662, 64,662 (Oct. 23, 2015) (to be codified at 40 C.F.R. pt. 60). The D.C. Circuit is currently entertaining a challenge to the regulations, which President Trump has announced his ambition to withdraw. See Order at 2, West Virginia v. EPA, No. 15-1363 (D.C. Cir. Apr. 28, 2017) (granting a sixty-day stay of litigation); Exec. Order No. 13,783, 82 Fed. Reg. 16,093, 16,094–96 (Mar. 31, 2017) (mandating the suspension, revi­sion, or rescission of numerous federal climate change reform plans). This state schism on climate change thus creates a powerful argument in favor of federal action, which could bind all states to achieving progress on decarbonization. 344 See Jonathan B. Wiener, Think Globally, Act Globally: The Limits of Local Climate Policies, 155 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1961, 1962 (2007) (“[S]ubnational state-level action is not the best way to combat global climate change. This is true even assuming that fore­stalling global climate change is of utmost importance, and even where the state-level poli­cies are individually well designed.”). But these arguments are orthogonal to this Article’s inquiry, which is of a narrower scope: Given the fact that no federal climate policy is likely to be forthcoming soon, should states seeking to decarbonize work together through their regional electricity markets to do so?

Using RTOs to address decarbonization simply does not have the same power to pull along laggard states. Because of RTOs’ voluntary membership and stakeholder-governance processes, laggard states would be perfectly capable of blocking any RTO decarbonization proposals that required them to go above and beyond on climate. 345 See supra sections III.B–.C. And even if a region were to figure out a way to allow certain of its members to pursue decarbonization goals absent full regional participation, 346 Cf. PJM, Advancing Zero Emissions Objectives, supra note 190, at 2 (proposing that a subregion of states within PJM could pursue carbon pricing, although these might have to be contiguous states). such cooperative action would not stop other states in the region from pursuing poli­cies aimed at propping up carbon-intensive resources. 347 There might be a legal differentiation, however, between state policies aimed at decarbonizing and state policies aimed specifically at keeping old plants from retiring simply to preserve jobs and economic benefits to the state. The latter type of state policy might be more vulnerable to a Dormant Commerce Clause challenge than state envi­ronmental initiatives. Cf. Vill. of Old Mill Creek v. Star, Nos. 17-cv-01163 & 17-cv-01164, 2017 WL 3008289, at *16 (N.D. Ill. July 14, 2017) (accepting the environmental purpose of Illinois’s ZEC program but hinting that a program aimed exclusively at in-state economic benefits would be vulnerable on these grounds). Accordingly, although state polarization argues for federal action, it does not lend force to pro­posals to regionalize decarbonization policy through electric­ity markets. 348 Unless, of course, a laggard state is willing to up its ambition as a condition of other states proceeding through the market construct—a contingency accounted for in my three variables. See supra section IV.A.

Conclusion

Scholars, regulators, and market participants all recognize that elec­tricity markets, in their current form, do not incentivize the rapid decar­bonization of the electricity sector necessary to respond to climate change, thereby forcing states to act on their own. This realization has provoked conversations at FERC, at RTOs, and among states as to whether these markets should be redesigned to accomplish states’ cli­mate change goals. This Article has questioned the use of redesigned electricity markets as a driver of decarbonization in the United States. In particular, this Article has pointed out the ways in which decarbonizing electricity is a social project that should be managed by politically accountable entities, working through public processes capable of chan­neling and incorporating numerous goals related to decarbonization.

Those who are committed exclusively to the most rapid decarboniza­tion possible are unlikely to be persuaded by this argument. It is true that in the present political climate, using electricity markets to respond to climate change would be an expedient and efficient pathway forward. Nevertheless, this Article has highlighted the risks that attend expedi­ency. If climate change policy is shunted into these markets rather than left open for public debate, states will have lost a significant amount of control over how decarbonization proceeds. Instead, these decisions will be made in quasi-private governance institutions with complex voting rules and opaque power structures, under murky jurisdictional bounda­ries that may make it hard for states to assert concordant control.

The technical intricacies inherent in discussions over integrating cli­mate policies and regional electricity markets often drive participants to put aside larger questions regarding the animating forces of climate pol­icy—at great peril. Debates over using electricity markets to accomplish decarbonization should in fact highlight the question of why climate change is a problem in the first place. After all, civilizations have crumbled and species have gone extinct due to climatic changes. 349 See Jared Diamond, Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed 77–308 (2005) (documenting and theorizing the collapse of many past societies); Elizabeth Kolbert, The Sixth Extinction: An Unnatural History 101–04 (2014). For many, the answer to this question is that the continued peaceful existence of humans on Earth—and the minimization of their suffering—is a worthy aim. 350 See Dale Jamieson, Reason in a Dark Time: Why the Struggle Against Climate Change Failed—And What It Means for Our Future 164–67, 179 (2014) (exploring this rationale for climate action and the challenges it presents for “commonsense” morality and concluding that the task at hand is “to live in productive relationship with the dynamic systems that govern a changing planet”); see also Steven C. Sherwood & Matthew Huber, An Adaptability Limit to Climate Change Due to Heat Stress, 107 Proc. Nat’l Acad. Sci. U.S. 9552, 9552 (2010) (explaining why an uninhabitable planet is a distinct pos­sibility, since a temperature increase of around 7°C would “call[] the habitability of some regions into question” for humans, and that “[w]ith 11–12°C warming,” most of “human population as currently distributed” would reside in uninhabitable regions). If the project of decarbonization is in service of the continued wellbeing of humanity—and, potentially, species beyond humans 351 See Kolbert, supra note 349, at 268 (arguing that humans are not “what’s most worth attending to”); Jedediah Purdy, After Nature: A Politics for the Anthropocene 249, 272 (2015) (arguing that understanding our present world as one where there is no “nature” apart may open space for reimagining a “post-humanism” that gives all forms of life equal value). —it must be part of a larger social conversation about how we want to live in communities in the future. These conversations are worth preserving for the public forum, in which debate, dissent, experimentation, and long-term social visions can continue to develop within and alongside decarboniza­tion policies in the coming decades.